Skip to main content

Open Access 25.04.2024

Metaphysical Status of Money and Sustainable Organizations and Ecosystems

verfasst von: Tiago Cardao-Pito, Jyldyz Abdyrakhmanova

Erschienen in: Philosophy of Management

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The current economic and societal production system gives money a magnified importance, overlooking other essential flows necessary for human survival and existence. It focuses on monetary indicators like profits, dividends, and GDPs to evaluate organizational production, while often disregarding outputs that harm the biosphere. Money is treated as the constitutive being (ousia) and attributed undemonstrated explanatory properties. Intangible flow theory helps eliminate this metaphysical status of money by recognizing that monetary flows are just one of many necessary flows for human survival and existence. Organizations deliver product-flows that require input-flows from and send output-flows back to the encompassing biosphere, whether they explicitly engage in environmentally friendly activities or not. Therefore, every organization is an ecological entity because it has a relationship with the biosphere, which participates in the manner through which humans integrate into their surrounding environment and relate to other living beings. Eliminating the metaphysical status of money integrates every organization in the biosphere, making organizations accountable for environmental harm caused by their activities. This can be achieved by deconstructing the metaphysical status of money in business models.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Introduction

The emergence of our climatic and environmental situation and the many forms of pollution caused by the production process are worsening, thereby traversing some of our planet’s boundaries. Therefore, we must develop new ideas and theories.
Sustainable and circular ecosystems have remarkable persuasiveness regarding pollution avoidance, recycling, and management of natural resources and waste.1 Previous research has made a distinction between organizations that participate in activities such as reducing, reusing, recovering, or recycling, which are deemed circular economies, and those that do not, which are deemed linear economies.2
As circular economy studies move to a more integrated approach, the influence of socio- cultural aspects has become more evident. More attention is required on the equitable distribution of resources, transparency, and stakeholder responsibilities in circular economy discourses.3 Furthermore, there is a need for bridging technical, managerial, socio-economic, environmental, and political perspectives.4
Unfortunately, only a limited number of firms explicitly commit to reducing, reusing, recovering, or recycling, and an even smaller number implement effective measures to implement them productively. Furthermore, firms that are and are not committed to sustainable and circular ecosystems can send polluting flows that cause environmental degradation to the surrounding biosphere.5
Nevertheless, these negative outputs are often treated as externalities to the production process. We suggest that these polluting flows be fully incorporated in our understanding of economic and societal production. In other words, we suggest eliminating the alibi that polluting flows are externalities of the production process. We define this reasoning as an alibi in the sense that production is claimed elsewhere, not in pollution flows. Granted, using the concept of externality, observers may alert to pollution and its consequences. However, polluting flows are treated as external to production. Accordingly, they are externalities. This alibi, which excuses polluting organizations, is invoked by various governments, firms, and scholars.6
We suggest that polluting flows and environmental harm caused by organizations must be considered an integral part of their productive processes. To eliminate the externality alibi, we apply a conception of intangible flow theory,7 namely the deconstruction of the metaphysical status of money into an empirical status. The metaphysical status of money consists of the attribution of explanatory properties to money, which is not demonstrated beyond the world of concepts in the physical world. In the metaphysical status of money, monetary flows are given ontological and epistemic primacy over other flows necessary for human survival and existence, such as flows related to food, clothes, transport, housing, and healthcare. Furthermore, monetary flows are invoked to justify pseudo-phenomena. A pseudo-phenomenon is a non-existent phenomenon that is employed as demonstrated and verified.8
To achieve this conceptual framework, one needs to consider the flows necessary for economic and societal production. Observe, for instance, the flows necessary for food to reach supermarket shelves or restaurant tables. Why should the flows of money be more important than the other flows necessary for the flows of food or the flows of food themselves? Alternatively, to put it another way, in the format of identifying the pseudo-phenomenon, why should monetary flows entirely explain the flows of food?
Monetary flows are held as the major purpose of production and as the creators/definers of commodities. Money is treated as the constitutive being (ousia9) and first cause of economic and societal phenomena. It is turned into the ontological basic entity. Money explains why the other things exist in management, organizational and economic phenomena, but money or monetary flows stand in no need of explaining.10 Consequently, production is defined through monetary indicators such as GDPs, profits, dividends, rents, interests, and related indicators.11 The concept of externality is associated with outwardness regarding economic and societal production, defined through monetary flows treated as the constitutive being, which is reflected in these indicators. In the empirical status of money, monetary flows are only one type of flow that is currently necessary for human survival and existence. Human beings, organizations, and societies are immersed in the biosphere. By the biosphere, we not only understand living beings but also the requirements for their existence of living beings in our planet’s atmosphere, hydrosphere, and geosphere.12
This study aims to demonstrate that when economic and societal production is conceptually integrated into the biosphere, the environmentally hostile concept of externality can be eliminated. Monetary flows are no longer treated as the constitutive being (ousia) and primary cause of economic and societal phenomena. Every business model is integrated into the biosphere because organizations are ecological entities that participate in the manner in which humans integrate into their surrounding environment and relate to other living beings. By ecology, we comprehend the study of the relationship between organisms and their surrounding environment, and to each other. This definition is also applicable to human beings (adapted from the Ecological Society of America 2023; Remmert 1980; Sarkar and Elliott-Graves 2016; Smith and Pimm 2023).
Although they are certainly heterodox, these contributions can have significant implications because most environmental degradation appears to be caused by production outputs. These damaging outputs are generally created to generate flows of money in the direction of specific organizations, states, and individuals. By eliminating the concept of externality and integrating every business model in the biosphere, we can better understand the urgency of adopting effective productive measures for reducing, reusing, recovering, and recycling for improving the relationship that every organization has with the biosphere.
The deconstruction of the metaphysical status of money produced in this article must not be confused with an anti-metaphysical stance, such as that of logical positivism or relativism in postmodernism/poststructuralism. On the contrary, it directly results from a metaphysical analysis, which demonstrates the relevance of inquiring about the basis, foundations, and possibilities for knowledge. The denial of metaphysical components in dominant theories or the denial of the very possibility of metaphysical analysis contribute to sabotaging the possibility of new theories that can contest dominant theories in management, economics, and other social sciences. Hence, these denials against metaphysical inquires contribute to the status quo and lack of renewal in these discipline.13
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. The next section describes the explanation for the existence of organizations that results from the metaphysical status of money. The third section describes the difficulty of finding alternative explanations for the existence of organizations while maintaining the metaphysical status of money. The fourth section reviews evidence that various of the firms that generate the largest monetary revenues have vast impacts upon the biosphere. The fifth section discusses how the empirical status of money can contribute to integrating every organization in the biosphere. The sixth section identifies directions for future research. It notes that the identification of the metaphysical status of money raises other interesting research questions, such as: [a] Why did the treatment of money as constitutive being (ousia) of economic and societal activity be under noticed and understudied in various disciplines? [b] When did the treatment of money as the constitutive being (ousia) of economic and societal activity originate? Furthermore, this section describes a specific example of possible future research, namely the recognition that many contemporary universities and academics are deeply affected by the metaphysical status of money. The last section concludes the study.

The Profit Motive that Results from the Metaphysical Status of Money

Metaphysical components are employed in contemporary theories to describe societies, markets and organizations.14 As described above, the metaphysical status of money is a concept derived from intangible flow theory. It describes situations in which monetary flows are treated as the constitutive being (ousia) and attributed superior explanatory capacity compared to other flows in economic and societal production. It commands organizational production to be primarily evaluated through monetary indicators such as profits, dividends, or GDPs.
The contemporarily dominant explanation for the existence of an organization is derived from this metaphysical status of money. Accordingly, organizations exist to increase monetary profits and, consequently, the wealth of their shareholders/owners15 (. This explanation is not only attributed to firms (or corporations) but also to governments and non-government organizations (NGOs) because we often hear and read that they should also be run as for-profit organizations.16
This explanation for the existence of organizations can be found in most areas of economics.17 In business, organizational, and management research derived from economics, the concept of competitive advantage translates to it. Accordingly, competitive advantage implies controlling factors that enable an increase in profit/shareholder wealth, either temporarily or in the long run.18 For instance, both the resource-based view19 and position view of firms20 claim that holding either key resources or industry positioning is the best route to attaining competitive advantage. Hence, these are described as the driving motives of organizations to increase monetary profit and shareholder wealth. Even a few recent attempts to discuss alternative purposes for the existence of an organization are constrained by the reasoning that any other possible organizational purpose must be subordinated to that of increasing profits/owners’ wealth.21
Nonetheless, the metaphysical status of money leads to overreliance on monetary motives, which can fundamentally detach organizations and societies from the biosphere upon which we are immersed. In research and in the news and over the internet there are plenty of examples of how a voracious thirst for profit threatens climate change, biodiversity, health, hunger, poverty, inequality, war, and so forth.22
Although some of these tribulations appear to have been on the increase, they are often deemed by many scholars to be externalities of functioning markets and the organizations that participate in them,23 as if the consequences arising in the biosphere from the monetary profit motive could be disconnected from the activities performed by organizations.
However, the widely advocated monetary profit motive treats organizations as black boxes that are (openly or covertly) obsessed with financial results (or the bottom line). In this context, organizations are automatically classified as being for profit, regardless of their structures, systems, and processes. Similarly, important initiatives from the circular economy can be understood as alien to the productive process when they do not impact firms’ profits (or financial performance, or the bottom line).
Paradoxically, this monetary profit motive does not really distinguish organizations nor does it explain how profits are attained. Furthermore, this profit motive also conveys a profound lack of sympathy toward understanding complex problems solved by contemporary organizations and their vital role in human survival and existence.24 Additionally, the profit motive obfuscates forms of organizing that occur outside the formal firm25 and recent technological forms of organizing that compete with traditional firms.26
Nevertheless, to tackle societal and environmental challenges and advance a sustainable economy, robust action seems to be required in the quest for alternatives to the profit motive.27 We need alternative explanations that can address the interrelatedness of economic, social, and environmental systems, and advance the relation between organizations and the biosphere.28

Difficulty of Detaching the Organizational Aim from the Metaphysical Status of Money

Nonetheless, alternatives to the monetary profit motive, derived from the metaphysical status of money, have been elusive. Remarkably, the stakeholder view of the organization has restored Aristotle’s (350, BC) ancient formulation that economic and social activity must be based on virtue and placed within the community (polis) of human beings29 and Polanyi’s (1944, 2001, 1977) view that markets are embedded in human societies. The stakeholder’s view has argued that various persons and groups (stakeholders) all have concerns related to organizations, beyond those of making money for shareholders/owners. Besides being created by humans, organizations can interact with many other humans, including workers, customers, suppliers, governments, neighbours, and interest groups and so forth.30
Furthermore, various studies have presented a theoretical and empirical argument favoring corporate social responsibility (CSR) and sustainable initiatives by for-profit firms.31 The United Nations proposed Sustainable Development Goals (SDG), which have wide-reaching implications for organizations.32 In addition, attempts at sustainable investing have been linked to the development of Environmental, Governance and Social (ESG) Investing and Standards, with the aim of proposing a triple bottom line involving the environment, economy, and society.33
However, despite the many positive contributions of these initiatives, they are still not entirely compelling. Undeniably, they are still subordinate to the concept that organizations exist because of the monetary profit motive, which results from the metaphysical status of money that attributes superior explanatory power to monetary flows over other flows necessary for human existence and survival.
Despite many valid and important contributions, to date, the stakeholder view does not clearly explain what binds all these people together around the organization.34 Furthermore, recent variations in stakeholder theory have attempted to reorient it toward the monetary profit motive, arguing that organizations’ concern for stakeholders is mainly instrumental for the drive to attain greater profitability.35 Likewise, several studies have attempted to link CSR programs to enhanced financial performance.36
Furthermore, there may be grey zones in distinguishing corporate social responsibility from corporate social irresponsibility.37 In August 2022, António Guterres, United Nations Secretary-General, criticized the greed of firms that had excessive profits while taking advantage of the energy crisis arising from inflation and war in Ukraine. He has urged Governments to “tax these excessive profits, and use the funds to support the most vulnerable people through these difficult times”.38 However, it would not be difficult to identify firms proclaiming a commitment to the UN’s Sustainable Development Goals among the firms criticized by the Secretary-General.
The Economist (2022) newspaper recently summarized a set of criticisms that are frequently lodged against ESG Investing and Standards, which include the following: a) lack of a coherent guide for firms to make trade-offs that are inevitable in any society, b) not being straight about incentives because they imply that good behavior is always more lucrative when this might be false (for instance, pollution and crime might be very lucrative), c) inconsistencies in the scoring system that are easily gamed, from which we can also deduct d) greenwashing, and e) the equivalent socialwashing.39

Firms Generating Large Monetary Flows can have Great Impacts Upon the Biosphere

This Section describes recent evidence that firms generating the largest amounts of monetary flow revenues have a significant impact on the biosphere. Monetary flows are not the constitutive being (ousia) but one type of flows among others currently necessary for human survival and existence. Cardao-Pito (2021a, Chapter 5) studied all firms that were listed during [2000–2017] in the stock markets of five large countries: China [36,790 observations, 3,520 organizations], Germany [10,648 observations, 968 organizations], Japan [58,115, 4,563], the UK [29,748, 3,115], and the US [29,948, 2,104].40
The sample comprises 14,217 firms in total. Among these firms, Cardao-Pito identified the 20 firms in each country’s subsample with the largest mean yearly monetary revenue. In total, he identified 100 firms. Rather than adopting the more common approach of comparing their stock market valuation (which is not yet entirely understood), this recent study analyzed exactly how much revenue these firms generated.
Table 1, which is divided by country, classifies these 100 firms according to their major activities. Although these organizations’ revenues are obtained from around the world, they are equivalent to a large proportion of their country´s average GDP. For instance, in Germany, the 20 largest average firms in terms of revenue represent approximately 48% of the average GDP. The equivalent percentage for China was 12%, with 35% for Japan, 51% for the UK, and 19% for the US.41 Hence, these organizations generate substantial monetary flows. By studying them, it is possible to better appreciate the relationship between monetary flows, product flows, and biosphere phenomena.
Table 1
The 20 highest-revenue listed firms in China, Germany, Japan, the UK, and the US [2000-2017] classified by their major activities
 
China sample
Germany sample
Japan sample
UK sample
US sample
Airline and travel companies
 
Lufthansa
 
Tui Travel
 
Automobile and transport machinery manufacturers
Saic Motor, China CNR
Volkswagen, Daimler, BMW, Audi, Continental
Toyota Motor, Honda Motor, Nissan Motor, Mitsubishi
 
General Motors, Ford
Communication firms involving commodities and physical structure
China United Communication Network
Deutsche Telekom, Deutsche Post
Japan Post, Nippon Telegraph and Telephone, NTT DoCoMo
Vodafone Group
AT&T, Verizon Communications
Construction and building structures related organizations
China State Construction and Engineering, China Vanke, Xiamen C&D, Xanghai Construction Group
    
Energy related, mining/extractive and chemical companies
China Petroleum and Chemicals, Minmetals, China Electric Power Equipment and Technology,
Uniper, E-ON, Basf, Innogi, Rwe, Bayer
JXTG Holdings, Nippon Oil
BP, Glencore, Shell Transport and Trading, SSE, Anglo American
Exxon Mobil, Chevron, Philips 66, ConocoPhilips, Valero Energy
Insurance organizations
China Pac, New China Life
Allianz, Muenchener Ruck
Japan Post Insurance, Nippon Life Insurance, Dai-ichi Life Holdings
Prudential, Aviva, Legal and General, Standard Life Abeerdeen
AIG
Intangible intensive companies
   
WPP
 
Other industrial manufacturing and conglomerates with several manufacturing operations
Baoshan Iron and Steel, HBIS Company
Siemens, ThyssenKrupp
Hitachi
Unilever, Imperial Brands
General Electrics, Berkshire Hathaway,
Physical machines and appliances manufacturers
Huawei Investment, Midea Group, Green Electric Appliances
 
Panasonic, Sony, Toshiba, Toyota Tsusho, Fujitsu
 
Apple, IBM, HP
Producers and distributers of health related products
   
Glaxosmithkline, Astrazeneca, Alliance Boots
McKesson, United Health Group, CVS Health, Cardinal Health
Retailers and intermediaries storing and delivering physical goods (commodities)
JD.Com, Suning.com, Power Diversity Automobile Trade
Ceconomy, Metro
Seven & I Holdings, Aeon
Tesco, Sainsbury, Morris Supermarkets
Wall-Mart
This table demonstrates that monetary flow generation can be highly dependent and impactful on the biosphere, which provides conditions for human survival and existence. The table approximately classifies by the activities performed the 20 listed firms that generated the largest revenue monetary inflows in five large countries, namely, China, Germany, Japan, the UK, and the US. The samples were obtained from the Refinitiv DATASTREAM Database. It contained 14,217 clearly identifiable organizations in the five country sub-samples: China [36,790 observations; 3,520 organizations], Germany [10,648 observations; 968 organizations], Japan [58,115; 4,563; the UK [29,748; 3,115], and the US [29,948; 2,104]. The sample covers a specific period for Germany, the UK, and the US [2000-2017] and for China and Japan [2002-2017, where data were unavailable for 2000 and 2001]
Cardao-Pito (2021a, Chapter 5)
Commodity intensity [i.e., physical-good intensity in the intangible flow theory framework] does not immediately imply greater revenues. For example, a simple 7–11 convenience store can have a large commodity intensity because it mostly delivers commodity flows to customers. However, the ensuing revenue may be modest. Notwithstanding, the organizations that generated the largest monetary flows in these country subsamples seem to be generally based on tangible flows that are utterly reliant on natural resources and the bio-physical world.
In this period, the firms that generated the greatest monetary revenues in the five samples were two companies related to energy, extractive, and chemical operations: China Petroleum and Chemicals, and BP in the UK; two car manufacturers, Toyota Motor in Japan and Volkswagen in Germany; and a large supermarket chain that is highly based on physical good (commodity) flows: Wall-Mart in the US. Clearly, all of these firms produce highly tangible (commodity intensive) product flows. With very few exceptions, the largest money-generating firms tend to have higher commodity flow tangibility.
Among these 100 firms, there are several organizations related to energy, extractive, and chemical manufacturing that require natural physical resources to produce and deliver their product flows. These findings appear to demonstrate contemporary societies’ reliance on energy, minerals, and raw materials that are extracted, transformed, transported, stored, and then delivered by these organizations.
All five samples contain conglomerates with physical manufacturing operations as the largest monetary flow generators. The prevalent type of organization present in each sample are organizations involved in enhancing human communication and Internet services, such as Vodafone in the UK, Deutsche Telekom in Germany, and NTT Docomo in Japan. Although human communication and Internet flows are largely intangible, geographically distant communication and the Internet both require commodities and hard physical infrastructures to be able to operate. In addition, apart from the UK sample, all samples contain highly tangible car manufacturers among the largest monetary flow generators, examples being organizations such as the SAIC motor in China, Nissan Motor in Japan, or Ford in the US.
The China, Japan, and US samples all contain several physical machine and appliance manufacturers among the largest monetary flow-generating firms, such as the Green Electric Appliance Group, Toshiba, or Apple. China is the only sample that contains organizations directly related to construction and building structures among the top 20 largest monetary flow-generating firms. The UK and US are the two samples that contain firms connected to human health, which could be related to their domestic health systems. However, medicines and medical machines require several inputs from the bio-physical world. Furthermore, organizations that provide health services require highly tangible hospitals, machines, furniture, ambulances, etc., as do pharmaceutical companies such as Glaxosmithkline and Astrazeneca in the UK, which are related to some degree of intangibility with R&D, patents, or marketing. Moreover, medicines and medical machines have different physical forms.
Among these 100 large monetary flow generators, a few organizations can traditionally be classified as intangible intensive. Nonetheless, intangible flow theory explains that this could be a misconstruction, because these firms are highly reliant on tangibility for their product flows. Examples include an airline (Lufthansa in Germany) and a travel company that owns planes in addition to hotels (Tui Travel in the UK). These two organizations can traditionally be classified as mere service providers; however, airways are highly dependent on tangible jet fuel, planes, airports, etc. Likewise, hotels require highly tangible physical structures, such as buildings, furniture, and machines.
Similarly, organizations that store and deliver physical goods can also be traditionally classified as mere service providers and thus as intangible intensive. In fact, their product flows are based on commodities; therefore, their product outflows are highly tangible. Examples include supermarket and retail store chains, such as JD.Com, Suning.com, Power Diversity Automobile Trade (in China), Ceconomy (in Germany), Seven & I Holdings and AEON (in Japan), Tesco, Sainsbury, Morris Supermarkets (in the UK), Wall-Mart (in the US), and gross wholesaler suppliers to supermarkets, retailers, and other shops, such as Metro (in Germany).
In each country subsample, there was at least one insurance company among the largest cash flow generator set. Clearly, a key resource for insurance organizations is money, in which monetary flows are highly tangible. Furthermore, insurance contracts can be classified as either (human) life (eg. term contracts, cash value contracts or hybrid contracts) or non-life (as property, houses, cars, factories, etc.). Most insurance contracts involve tangible fixtures and conditions.
The one organization among these 100 firms that could be considered to produce product flows with higher intangibility is WPP, a large advertising and communication company (in the UK). However, its operations are far from entirely intangible. According to its 2017 annual report, the WPP employed 203,000 in 3,000 (physical) offices located in 112 countries around the world. These employees require highly tangible physical flows to survive and exist, let alone work.
Table 1 further confirms the association between monetary flow generation and tangible flows, both of which rely on natural resources and the biophysical world. Furthermore, those tangible flows rely on human-related intangible flow dynamics to be produced and delivered. The data from these samples were terminated in 2017. In recent years, however, large technological firms such as Alphabet (Google’s parent company), Apple, Amazon, Microsoft, Tencent, and Alibaba have all been increasing their flows of products, and consequently, their monetary inflows. Nevertheless, their relationship with tangibility can be proven by the many commodities delivered by Apple, Amazon, or Alibaba to members of society, and the hundreds of thousands of employees that these six firms employ around the world.42
As exhibited in this section, some of the firms in China, Germany, Japan, the UK, and the US, whose product flows currently generate the most severe impacts on the environment, are also those that generate some of the largest annual monetary revenues (e.g., energy-related firms, mining/extractive and chemical companies, airline and travel companies, and automobile and transport machinery manufacturers that deliver machines based on combustion engines).

Organizations are Ecological Entities

In the metaphysical status of money where money is treated as the constitutive being (ousia), monetary metrics have an explanatory prevalence over other flows in economic and societal production. In the empirical status of money suggested by intangible flow theory, monetary flows are only one type of flow currently required for human survival and existence. Monetary flows have no explanatory primacy over the other flows necessary for human survival and existence. This section explains how the elimination of the metaphysical status of money contributes to the advancement of sustainable ecosystems. Table 2 summarizes the major contributions of this study.
Table 2
Deconstruction of the metaphysical status of money into an empirical status: organizations are ecological entities
 
Metaphysical status of money
Empirical status of money
Status of monetary flows
Economic and societal production is defined in terms of monetary flows, and related measures such as GDPs, profits, dividends, rents, interests and so forth
Monetary flows are only one type of flows amongst the flows currently necessary for human survival and existence
Concept of externality
Impacts of production in the biosphere are treated as externalities when they are not explicitly reflected on the organization’s monetary flows, or have only negative consequences (e.g., pollution)
The concept of externality is eliminated. Economic and societal production is integrated in the biosphere
Circular and linear economy
Circular economy is defined in terms of a limited number of important activities such as reducing, reusing, recovering, and recycling. Organizations that do not engage in these activities are said to be part of a linear economy. Nevertheless, these activities risk being considered as externalities of production
Every organization has a relationship with the biosphere. Important activities such as reducing, reusing, recovering, and recycling have key roles in improving that relationship
Still, organizations that do not engage in those activities also have a relationship with the biosphere. The artificial separation between circular and linear economy is removed
Business models
Business models for the circular economy generally consider only those organizations that explicitly adhere to activities such as reducing, reusing, recovering, and recycling
Every business model has a relationship with the surrounding biosphere
The authors
In their recent review, Dzhengiz et al. (2023) proposed that an important requirement to advance the case for the circular economy is identifying and analyzing in-house assumptions, root-metaphor assumptions, and ideological assumptions in circular economy research. We agree. Nevertheless, we add that there is also a need to inquire about other assumptions that are broadly imbued in business, management, organizational, and economic (BMOE) research. These assumptions can also pose obstacles to sustainable ecosystem agendas. One of these obstacles is the metaphysical status of money in BMOE research.
Indeed, the understanding of sustainable and circular ecosystems is not entirely consensual among organizations and among researchers.43 Furthermore, circular economy initiatives by firms require political support from governments,44 organizational ecosystems,45 and consumers and other stakeholders.46
Because of money’s metaphysical status, however, monetary flows are given an explanatory prevalence over other production flows. As noted earlier, economic and societal production are often considered in terms of monetary indicators (e.g., GDPs, profits, dividends, rents, interests, and related indicators). Invoking the profit motive to explain the existence of organizations is a consequence of the metaphysical status of monetary flows. Likewise, output flows that are not directly reflected in the generation of monetary flows are often treated as externalities regardless of how harmful they can be to the biosphere.
We suggest that the empirical status of money provides grounds for eliminating the concept of externalities. In fact, monetary flow generation might be the major cause of the various tribulations that human societies currently suffer in their relationships with a degrading environment. Several firms whose product flows currently generate the most severe impacts on the environment are also those that generate some of the largest annual monetary revenues (e.g., energy-related firms, mining/extractive and chemical companies, and automobile and transport machinery manufacturers that deliver machines based on combustion engines).
Various of these firms can have meritorious initiatives involving, for example, what is deemed a circular economy, corporate social responsibility programs, ESG reporting programs, or adoption of renewable energy/emission-saving technologies. However, many of their product flows systematically contribute to large-scale damage to the environment. Isolated financial analyses of profits (or monetary value created) cannot allow us to grasp the many negative impacts of these firms’ activities. On the other hand, their flow of products contributes to further explaining their profit generation systems and impacts on the environment. We propose that damage to the environment caused by these firms is an integral part of their business model. Thus, the artificial separation between so-called circular and linear economies is not only redundant but also dangerous in that it can be used to excuse serial organizational wrongdoers.
Undeniably, the adaptation of business models to sustainable initiatives is remarkably important.47 Yet, some scholars have noted that there may not always be a business case for these initiatives because they bring costs and trade-offs.48 Furthermore, this business model approach risks the addition of maintaining the current productive system remarkably intact despite the serious crises we face.49
Firms have arisen in a historical context. A more advanced form of organizing may be developed in the future, which can replace corporations. However, these new organizational forms must still solve the problem of how the flow of products can be delivered to members of society in an efficient, effective, and environmentally sustainable manner. Contemporarily, firms (corporations) are probably the most effective and efficient organizational forms for handling several complex flows of products. These product flows are highly relevant to contemporary human societies. For instance, in a supermarket chain, we can find food, drinks, cooking utensils, hygiene products, cleaning products, and many other items vital to our current existence and survival. The numerous flows in economic and societal production offer opportunities for future research.
The business model approach, derived from the metaphysical status of money, can have negative side effects on the environment and climate. We suggest that the concept of a business model related to sustainable ecosystems should not consider monetary flow as the definitive flow of economic and societal production. Rather, monetary flows must be treated as a type of empirical flow that is currently necessary for human survival and existence. This transformation integrates every organization in the biosphere. Firms that engage and do not engage in activities to reduce, reuse, recover, or recycle require input flows from and send output flows back to the biosphere. Therefore, to a substantial extent, every organization has a circular relationship with the biosphere, which we suggest should be acknowledged in every business model. Every organization is an ecological entity. To a significant extent, some of the most demanding problems for humankind are ecological, such as food and energy sources, climatic crises, species extinctions, pollution, and many other political and sociological problems (Bodin et al. 2019; Smith and Pimm 2023). Depending on the manner in which they are managed, organizations can either help solve or worsen these demanding problems.

Monetary Flows are not the Constitutive Being (Ousia) of Economic, Organizational, and Societal Phenomena: the Necessary Reoccurrence of Metaphysics

The demonstration that monetary flows are considered the constitutive beings (ousia) in much economic, management, and related research is not an anti-metaphysical stance. Rather, it is the output of a metaphysical analysis that exhibits the relevance of metaphysical inquiries regarding the conditions and possibilities for knowledge in social science disciplines.
From these findings, at least, two additional questions that need to be addressed in future research: [a] Why did the treatment of money as constitutive being of economic and societal activity remain under identified and understudied in various disciplines? [b] When did the treatment of money as the constitutive being of economic and societal activity originate? After discussing these questions, we will present an example of possible research involving the metaphysical status of money: The contemporary university.

Why did the Metaphysical Status of Money Remain Unnoticed for so Long?

Although this possibility needs further investigation in future research with much-appreciated help from other researchers, it seems possible that question ([a]) is related to antimetaphysics schools prevalent in the twentieth and twenty-first centuries, namely, the logical positivist/empiricist school and relativism in postmodernism/poststructuralism.
Logical positivism/empiricism claims to exclude metaphysical speculation from the realm of meaningful discourse because knowledge can only result from experience.50 This school is highly influential in economics and economic-oriented research in other disciplines.51 For instance, the late Milton Friedman, one of the most well-known advocates that firms exist to generate monetary income to their owners/shareholders,52 clearly promotes this perspective in his “Methodology of Positive Economics”.53 He assumed the positivist/empiricist view that economic models and theories do not matter if they have predictive ability over empirical phenomena (“predictive power for the class of phenomena which it is intended”, p. 9). Thus, he refuses inquiries about the legitimacy of metaphysical claims in economic models and theories under the auspices of alleged empirical confirmation. In our view, the importance of empirical evidence is undeniable. However, the positivist/empiricist school’s position is untenable because without inquiring about the conditions and possibility of knowledge, it is not viable to demonstrate either causality or consequence of models and theories.
Postmodernist/poststructuralist research is popular in many critical management studies.54 It is often deemed as major alternative and hope against mainstream economic and management theories. However, this school of thought has been associated with relativism.55 It is possible to find some of its writers aligning with at least one of three forms of relativism56: (i) metaphysical (transcendental) relativism for doubting the existence of a real world (of, say, objects, properties and relations outside our social and bio-mental constructions); (ii) epistemological (or scientific) relativism for advocating that science cannot have empirical instruments to describe a real world besides our human constructions; and (iii) semantic relativism for suggesting that human languages cannot describe a real world apart from our human constructions. Semantic relativism may also entail claims on how institutions and social arrangements enable discourses into being.
For instance, one influential postmodernist/poststructuralist writer went so far as to declare the end of the formation of new theories (that he deemed as mere metanarratives or grand narratives),57 denying the possibility of a means for sensing and perceiving (aesthesis58) the world outside the human being. Thus, while postmodernist/poststructuralist researchers behave as rivals to mainstream positivist theorists, the latter and former are allies in their antimetaphysics stance. The disdain of metaphysical analysis in both schools might be an important cause of the perpetuation of the metaphysical status of money.
Indeed, in vast sections of our world, as noted by Adorno in a lecture in1965, metaphysics has become “a term of abuse, a synonym for idle speculation, mere nonsense and heaven knows what other intellectual vices”.59 Nevertheless, the anti-metaphysics stance has specific consequences, because it denies admission to the conditions and possibilities of knowledge. Thus, it is highly protective of currently dominant theories and philosophies because anti-metaphysics sabotages the possibility of alternative theoretical formulations.60 When not entirely understood phenomena are in need of explaining, denial of new theory creation implies the resource to current theories. Hence, anti-metaphysics tacitly supports economic systems and social groups protected by dominant social theories.
The treatment of money as the constitutive being (ousia) of economic and societal phenomena is highly protective for those who have a lot of money. Nevertheless, anti-metaphysics is a self-contradictory stance because it is undeniably a metaphysical position. Likewise, the claim that everything is relative is unsustainable, because this sentence is only true if it is absolute (non-relative). On the other hand, if the sentence is false then something is not relative as claimed by relativism.61

When did the Metaphysical Status of Money Originate?

Question [b] regarding the origins of the treatment of money as the constitutive being of economic and societal activity likewise needs to be further investigated in future research. This question is likely related to the origin of economic ideas. In our society, as noted by Gare (2013, p. 122), it is not the philosophers who provide ideas that define right and wrong action or ways of living, but economists.62 Their effective ethical discourse implies that greed, egoism and using others as mere instruments63 are now considered virtues. Unlike ethical philosophers, economists are amply influential. Their ideas constrain every sphere of public and private life.64
Gare65 and Adorno66 find that the metaphysical ideas of our time still follow in the footsteps of the framework laid out by the ancient Greek philosopher Plato. As described by Adorno, criticisms of Plato’s philosophy are also ways to rescue his ideas. Hence, it could be conceivable that the metaphysical status of money results from a certain extent of Neoplatonism that could pervade economic thinking. Plato identified universal beings before particular things (universalia ante rem), which however define particular things. For instance, all dogs have common universal features that exist before each particular dog. Thus, one could raise the hypothesis that in management, economics, and other interrelated sciences, money is treated as the Platonic universal being of economic and societal activity, its perfect form.
Nonetheless, this hypothesis does not sit well with the treatment Plato himself gave to money. In his political philosophy, Plato had a highly stratified view of society, which he often expressed in the Republic.67 Plato divided an archetypal society into three groups, namely, the rulers (philosopher-kings that should be driven by reason), guardians (soldiers, driven by the spirit), and common people of producers (who he somewhat disdained and include labourers, peasants, merchants, or slaves driven by appetites and impulses). In Plato’s hierarchy, reason ought to rule over spirit, appetites, and impulses.
However, Plato despised the use of money, which he considered an illusory form to be allowed only for what he deemed as lower classes. Plato locates money-loving in appetitive/impulsive soul along with physical cravings like hunger and lust. For Plato, property and money are corruptors and represent a threat to social cohesion.68 Thus, to avoid the corruption of rulers and guardians, these members of society should have their needs attended, but they should not own property or handle gold or silver (money).69 Hence, while Plato supposed the existence of universal beings that exist before particular beings, he did not attribute the role of universal constitutive being (ousia) to money.
An alternative hypothesis is that the metaphysical status of money resulted as an unintended consequence of the metaphysical and economic ideas of Plato’s disciple Aristotle. Although often presented in rivalry with Plato, Aristotle’s metaphysics accepted much of the framework laid out by his professor.70 However, Aristotle rejected the existence of universal beings before the particular beings, preferring to look out for universal beings in the particular things (universalia in re or in rebus). This conception is related to Aristotle’s view of money, which attempts to distinguish between natural and non-natural use of money.71
The natural kind would be the one where money is used as an instrument for attending to human needs such as food, shelter, childbearing, or comfort. On the other hand, in the non-natural type, money is employed with the purpose of accumulating more monetary wealth in itself. These two concepts are related to two other concepts, namely: household and state management (oikonomy), and exchange (chrematistics). Aristotle understood the household and community (pollis) as deeply linked. The community starts in households, and the household is the model for state management of a community (polis).
To Aristotle, oikonomy ought to be based on natural activities to meet human needs, whereby in some cases money might not even be necessary. Nonetheless, money was necessary in exchange (chrematistics). For Aristotle, money has both the property of being a natural and non-natural constitutive being (ousia). In both definitions, we can verify the attribution of a metaphysical status of money. However, there is nothing natural about the use of money. Money is a purelu human creation.
Although a formidable philosopher, Aristotle was a man of his time. His concept of the natural use of money can be equated to his other concept of the natural slave, where he defined that some people are naturally born to be slaves.72 There is no proof that money or slaves are naturally constituted. Even in what Aristotle called the natural use of money, he often treated money as the constitutive being (ousia) that explains other economic and social elements, not what needs to be explained. However, the distinction between the natural and non-natural use of money is indefensible because money remains the same empirical being.
Furthermore, Aristotle's critique of the abusive employment of money in exchange may have unintentionally provided the foundations for the metaphysical status of money in economics, management, and interrelated research programs. Aristotle defined non-natural the use of money in exchange the conduct that occur when someone acts with the purpose of accumulating more monetary wealth in itself. Interests in loans (usury as understood at the time, or “the birth of money from money”) and exploitative trading practices have special incidence in his definition of the non-natural use of money:
“There are two sorts of wealth-getting, as I have said; one is a part of household -management, the other is retail trade: the former necessary and honorable, while that which consists in exchange is justly censured; for it is unnatural, and a mode by which men gain from one another. The most hated sort, and with the greatest reason, is usury, which makes a gain out of money itself, and not from the natural object of it. For money was intended to be used in exchange, but not to increase at interest. And this term interest, which means the birth of money from money, is applied to the breeding of money because the offspring resembles the parent. Wherefore of an modes of getting wealth this is the most unnatural.” Aristoteles (350 BC, Book 1, Part XI)
Although presenting a critique, Aristotle offered enemies of the conception of social responsibility towards others in the polis (community) a way to undermine non-monetary social relations. Enemies of social responsibility simply must prioritize monetary flows over other flows necessary for human survival and existence. They simply have to either focus on exchange (chresmatic) based on money and ignore all else, or use exchange (chresmatic) based on money to explain economic and societal production and the human relation with the biosphere. Accordingly, money could be turned into the constitutive being (ousia) of human organization, society, and the biosphere.
Writing in the nineteenth century, Sismondi understood the transformation being operated in economics (or political economy, as it was called at the time).73 He travelled across Europe and directly testified to many factory workers’ miserable livelihoods and how easily they could be replaced by machinery. Sismondi identified the term chrematistics ("Chrématistique”74) in Aristoteles to represent the non-natural use of money (for one’s enrichment and self-fruition), hence, to represent an abandonment of the focus in human toil and existence. He understood that the focus on chrematistics advocated by several economists was a reorientation of political economy’s focus from humankind to monetary wealth.
Sismondi warned that economics (political economy and interrelated disciplines) was being transformed into an “ occult science” losing contact with facts for the purpose of better calculation of monetary wealth in chrematistic theories.75 Yet, it is the metaphysical status of money, where money is treated as the constitutive being (ousia) of the flows necessary for human survival and existence, which enables the occult science and practices identified by both Sismondi and Aristotle.
As explained above, however, the deconstruction of the metaphysical status of money into an empirical status confirms the relevance of metaphysics. This is not the relativist deconstruction in which nothing can allegedly resist in the end. Relativism and antimetaphysics are self-defeating positions. Likewise, to remove the metaphysical status of money, one needs not to fall into pure idealism (mentalism) or nominalism denying the possibility and conditions of human knowledge over physicality (matter).
The current analysis does not exclude (or confirm) the possibility of the existence of ontological entities and categories. What it does is to remove the status of constitutive being (ousia) from of money. Rather than being the primary explanator of economic and societal production and human relation with the biosphere, monetary flows are what needs to be explained. Why do monetary flows flow and to where? Why do some people and groups hold privileged positions regarding the flows of money? These questions will only be properly addressed if money ceases to be the main explanator of human societies and our relationship with the biosphere.

The Metaphysical Status of Money in the University: a Brief Example of Possible Future Research Avenues

Future research may find it interesting to inquire about many organizational and non-organizational phenomena connected to the metaphysical status of money. For a brief example, we need to look not much further than the many contemporary universities where the generation of monetary flows seems to be gaining more importance than other contributions made by academics and other staff members.
Many contemporary universities are moving from a view through which scholars are to be appreciated for their curiosity to advance our understanding of the world, upholding the quest for truth and the conditions for doing this, and their lectures to young students (the next generations). Plato and Aristotle, mentioned above (and we could look out for many other philosophers), were deeply concerned with their work, which still contributes to philosophical and scientific debates in our own time. Although this is impossible to confirm, their lectures in the academy (founded by Plato) and Lyceum (founded by Aristotle) must have been somewhat extraordinary.
Currently, many academics find themselves employed in universities that are managed as tertiary organizations primarily concerned with the monetary bottom-line.76 Their academic,is assessed through indicators connected to monetary metrics. For example, a) obtaining monetary grants elsewhere; b) working in schools that pay high salaries to the faculty; or c) publishing in journals with so-called high rankings (regardless of what has been published) that will allow their school to claim better status in school rankings and accreditation processes thereby attracting students who pay higher enrolment fees (hence better contributing to the monetary bottom-line).
For many academics nowadays, the monetary flows they help generate to their universities and/or themselves can be considered more relevant than the flows of ideas, discoveries and lectures they produce. This may have several consequences for the quality, integrity, dissemination, and direction of their work, as well as their biases, conflicts of interests and eventual emotional damage.77 Furthermore, it may promote the tokenization of schools and journal rankings, and the development of a highly profitable industry in academic publishing.78 There are powerful beneficiaries of this status quo, who will be against substantial change. Consequently, however, important lines of research and inquiry can be diverted, sabotaged, or abandoned.79 The monetary status of money has profound implications for contemporary universities and their role in society. This is an example of a possible avenue for future research. Metaphysics impact contemporary universities and scholars.

Conclusion

Deconstruction of the metaphysical status of money into an empirical status is not an anti-metaphysical stance. In contrast, it results from a metaphysical analysis and demonstrates the relevance of metaphysics in the social sciences. As shown above, eliminating the metaphysical status of money contributes to eliminating the mainstream concept of externality. When money ceases to be treated as the constitutive being (ousia) of economic and societal activity, what occurs or exists with no direct reflection on monetary flows can no longer be automatically externalized in relation to economic and societal activity.
Therefore, the elimination of the metaphysical status of money contributes to the integration of organizations in the biosphere, organizational ecosystems, and with human beings to whom products are delivered. In the empirical status of money, monetary flows are just one type of flow among the many necessary for human survival and existence. Economic and societal production cannot be defined merely through monetary metrics such as GDPs, profits, dividends, rents, interests, and so forth.
This explanation adds to our understanding of how monetary flows, and hence, profits, are generated. It is not difficult to find specific examples of organizations with high levels of monetary flow generation, which are perhaps organizations whose product flows cause the greatest harm to our home planet. This harm persists even after considering commendable circular economy and corporate social responsibility initiatives, or the adoption of innovative technology that these firms engage in.
However, these firms’ financial results (or profits) alone would deem them very successful corporations. The empirical status of money demonstrates that the harm that firms cause to the planet is an integral part of how their monetary flows, and thus, their profits, are generated. This harm is an integral part of a business model. We propose that future research consider our proposal to make redundant the distinction between circular and linear economies, which can be invoked to excuse some serious polluters.
Business model frameworks must not consider the monetary flow as the definitive flow of economic and societal production. Rather, monetary flows are empirical flows among the many flows currently necessary to deliver flows of products to the members of society. Alternative forms of organizing for sustainable human societies must address the reality of the flow of products delivered to members of society, which is vital for our preservation and being. We suggest a new approach for business models in the context of our immersion in the biosphere, where every organization is an ecological entity because it participates in the manners through which humans integrate into their surrounding environment and relate to other living beings. Organizations are ecological entities whether they explicitly engage in environmentally friendly activities or not.
In the future, researchers, students, and other people interested in organizing may confirm the research potential of attributing an empirical status to monetary flows in the context of the biosphere. Following these proposals, future research may find it fruitful to further inquire about the productive flows organized by firms (corporations), other organizational forms, and their organizational ecosystems. Given the damages caused by a rapacious hankering for monetary profits in the context of major societal and environmental challenges we human beings currently face, feasible alternatives are urgently needed.
As explained above, some important questions need to be addressed in future research. We have introduced two of these: [a] When did the treatment of money as the constitutive being (ousia) of economic and societal activity originate? [b] Why did the treatment of money as constitutive being of economic and societal activity remain under notice and understudied in various disciplines? We have also exemplified a brief example of possible future research regarding an organization that may be highly impacted by the metaphysical status of money: The contemporary university.

Acknowledgements

Cristina Neesham (the editor), two anonymous referees and (the late) João da Silva Ferreira.

Declarations

Competing Interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Fußnoten
1
Blomsma and Brennan (2017); Geng et al. (2019); George et al. (2015); Hecht et al. (2012); Kirchherr et al. (2023); Leipold et al. (2023); Lüdeke-Freund et al. (2019); Pedneault et al. (2023)
 
2
See for example: Kopnina (2021); Dzhengiz et al. (2023); Morseletto (2023); Neves and Marques (2022).
 
3
Temesgen et al. (2021); Chedrak et al. (2023, p. 16).
 
4
Temesgen et al. (2021); Leipold et al. (2023).
 
5
Corvellec et al. (2022); Eppinger (2022); D’Itria and Aus (2023); Linder and Williander (2017); Lüdeke et al. (2019); Kirchherr et al. (2017); Sunny (2021); Niero et al. (2021); Roquebert and Debucquet (2022).
 
6
Van den Bergh (2010); Boudreaux and Meiners (2019); Figge et al. (2022); Owen et al. (2020); Liebowitz and Margolis (1994); Willman and Pepper (2020).
 
7
More details about this theory can be found in Cardao-Pito (2021a, 2012, 2016).
 
8
Cardao-Pito (2021a, Chapters 1 and 3).
 
9
Ousia (οὐσία) is a term used since ancient Greek metaphysics when it was employed by philosophers such as Plato and Aristotle. In contemporary philosophy this term is often understood as being and ontic. There was not a direct translation of the word to Latin, and thus Roman philosophers as Seneca or Cicero, and subsequent scholastic philosophers who wrote in Latin as Saint Augustine used alternatives such as substance or essence to define this term. These translations subsisted during many centuries and are still employed. However, we adopt the contemporary interpretation that the translation for ousia in the study of metaphysics is that of the study of being or ontology. As defined by Aristotle, constitutive or primary ousia are “the ontological basic entities. They are the things by reference to which we explain why the other things exist, but whose existence itself stands in no need of explaining” (Loux 2008, p. 2).
 
10
Idem.
 
11
Cardao-Pito (2021a, Chapters 1 and 3; 2016; 2012).
 
12
Cardao-Pito (2021a, p. 3).
 
13
Adapted from (2021a).
 
14
As noted by Schwarzkopf (2012).
 
15
Friedman (1970); Cardao-Pito (2021b); George et al. (2021); Flew (1976); Lux (2003)
 
16
See for instance Gray (1991); Deem and Brehony (2005); Lane (2002); Reiter and Klenk (2019).
 
17
Cardao-Pito (2017, 2021a, b, c); Flew (1976); Lux (2003)
 
18
Azeem et al. (2021); Bocken and Geradts (2020); Dagnino et al. (2021); Porter (1985a, b); Christensen (2001); Coyne (1986); Barney (1995); Powell (2001); Wu and Li (forthcoming).
 
19
Penrose (1959); Wernerfelt (1984); Barney (1991); Freeman et al. (2021).
 
20
Porter (1985a, 1996); Clegg et al. (2020)
 
21
See for instance: George et al. (2021); Gartenberg et al. (2019); Mayer (2021).
 
22
Mahoney and McGahan (2007); George et al. (2016); Howard-Grenville et al. (2019), Kunisch et al. (2020); Sadler-Smith and Akstinaite (2022); Willman and Pepper (2020).
 
23
Van den Bergh (2010); Boudreaux and Meiners (2019); Owen et al. (2020); Liebowitz and Margolis (1994); Willman and Pepper (2020).
 
24
Cardao-Pito (2017, 2021a, b).
 
25
Ahrne and Brunsson (2019); Mahoney et al. (2009); Kaul and Luo (2018); Mair and Rathert (2021); Josifidis and Supic (2021).
 
26
Davis (2016); Marquis (2020); Billinger and Workiewicz (2019).
 
27
Blok (2021); Dzhengiz et al. (2023); Ferraro et al. (2015); Feger and Mermet (2022); George et al. (2016); Mair and Rathert (2021); Jammulamadaka et al. (2021); Painter-Morland (2015); Russo-Spena et al. (2021); Thomas and Ritala (2022).
 
28
Bhar et al. (2022); Stough et al. (2022); Blomsma et al. (2023); Feger and Mermet (2022); George et al. (2016); Hiquet et al. (2023); Mair and Rathert (2021); Heikkurinen et al. (2021); Jammulamadaka et al. (2021); Nyberg and Wright (2016); Nyberg et al. (2022); Raworth (2017); Russo-Spena et al. (2021); Pek (2023); Perey et al. (2018); Panwar et al. (2022); Thomas and Ritala (2022); Kurucz et al. (2014); Marcus et al. (2010); Sunny (2021); Waddock (2022).
 
29
Aristotle (350 BC); Hühn and Meyer (2023).
 
30
See for instance Laplume et al. (2008); Freeman et al. (2004); Freeman et al. (2007); Gibson (2000); Fassin (2009).
 
31
Margolis and Walsh (2003); Flammer (2015); Kaul and Luo (2018); Goodell (1972); Latapí Agudelo et al. (2019).
 
32
Xu et al. (2021); Obel and Kallehave (2022); Jamali et al. (2022); Lemaire and Limbourg (2019).
 
33
Sherwood and Pollard (2018); Arvidsson and Dumay (2022); Kapil and Rawal forthcoming; Glavas and Mish (2015).
 
34
See for instance Lepak and Snell (1999); Mahoney and Kor (2015); Post et al. (2002); Russo and Perrini (2010).
 
35
See for instance McGahan (2021); He and Chittoor (2022); Cohen (2023); Freeman et al. (2021); Barnett (2022).
 
36
See for instance Okafor et al. (2021); Brooks and Kumar (2023); Gao et al. forthcoming; Barnett (2022); Awaysheh et al. (2020); Ho et al. (2021).
 
37
Clarck et al. (2022).
 
38
Cited in Nicholls (2022).
 
39
Adapted from Economist (2022); see also Arvidsson and Dumay (2022); Abhayawansa and Tyagi (2021); Cort and Esty (2020); Crace and Gehman (2023); van Bommel et al. (2023).
 
40
For China and Japan the period was [2002–2017] because the data was unavailable for 2000 and 2001.
 
41
Cardao-Pito (2021a, Chapter 5).
 
42
For instance, in March 2024, according to Google Finance, Alphabet (the parent of Google) employed 182,502 members of staff, Microsoft employed 221,000 members of staff, Meta (Facebook, Whatsapp and Instagram) employed 67,317 members of staff, and Ali Baba 219,260 members of staff.
 
43
Corvellec et al. (2020); D’Itria and Aus (2023); Dzhengiz et al. (2023); Kirchherr et al. (2017); Lieder and Rashid (2016); Leipold et al. (2023); Ghisellini et al. (2016); Tanguy et al. (2023).
 
44
Amengual and Bartley (2022); Bauwens et al. (2020); Droege et al. (2023); Patala et al. (2022); Salmivaara and Kibler (2020); Ranta et al. (2018); Schultz and Reinhardt (2022).
 
45
Thomas and Ritala (2022); Kapoor (2018); Jacobides et al. (2018); Shipilov and Gawer (2020); Yonatany (2017).
 
46
Kuhlmann et al. (2023); Pretner et al. (2021); Bocken and Konietzko (2022); Schillebeeckx et al. (2022).
 
47
Bocken and Short (2016); Centobelli et al. (2020); De Angelis and Ianulardo (2020); Eikelenboom and de Jong, (2022); DiVito et al. (2022); Ferasso et al. (2020); Frishammar and Parida (2019); Lüdeke-Freund et al. (2018); Neligan et al. (2023); Parida et al. (2019); Plewnia and Guenther (2021).
 
48
Eppinger (2022); Frei et al. (2020); Castro and Lopes, (2024); Dentoni et al. (2021); Garcia-Quevedo et al. (2019); Hahn and Pinkse (2022); Kopnina (2021); Linder and Williander (2017); Olesson et al. (2023); Neesham et al. (2023); Piila et al. (2022); Van Loon et al. (2018)
 
49
Corvellec et al. (2022); de Bakker et al. (2020); Dzhengiz et al. (2023); Kjaer et al. (2019); Mikkelson (2021); Panwar et al. (2022); Norris (2019); Sadler-Smith and Akstinaite (2022).
 
50
Gohner and Schrenk (2024) provide an introduction about this school.
 
51
See for instance McCloskey (2022); Drakopoulos (2024)
 
52
See for instance Friedman (1970)
 
53
Friedman (1953).
 
54
See for instance Adler et al. (2007, p. 140–142); Bowden (2021); Hassard (1999).
 
55
Postmodernism/poststructuralism are often directly associated to either relativism or skepticism in reference to the ancient relativist school with that name. See for instance Baghramian (2004); Cardao-Pito (2021a); Kukla (2000); Norris (1997); Plotnitsky (2017); Ward (1997); Zagorin (1999).
 
56
We are following here the Kukla’s (2000) typology of relativism.
 
57
Lyotard (1984, 1997 p. xxiv).
 
58
Although the philosopher Immanuel Kant is often attributed the formulation of sensing and understanding, the related formulation of sensing and perceiving was discussed for thousands of years. In the ancient Greek world it had a specific word for it, namely, ‘aesthesis’. See for instance Shields and Hardy (2024).
 
59
Adorno (1965, 2001).
 
60
Adapted from Cardao-Pito (2021a).
 
61
In the ancient world, the problem of relativism being self-refuting was demonstrated by Plato (In Theaetetus) (Plato 2013), Democritus, Aristoteles and several Stoic philosophers (Burnyeat 1976a, b; Lee 2005; Cardao-Pito 2021a).
 
62
Gare (2013) also presents the argument that the economists are assisted by their “offsiders the psychologists”, which for reasons of space we do not examine in here.
 
63
Greed was added in adaptation Gare reference to egoism and using others.
 
64
Gare (2013)
 
65
Gare (2013); Adorno (1965, 2001, Lecture four).
 
66
Adorno (1965, 2001).
 
67
Often through the position of his Socrates.
 
68
See Plato (375 BC); Dupont (2017); Gooch (2000); Blackhouse (2002); Rothbard (2006).
 
69
Idem.
 
70
Adorno (1965, 2001); Sach (2024)
 
71
A further summary of Aristotle view on money can be found in Meikle (1994).
 
72
Aristotle (350 BC): “But is there any one thus intended by nature to be a slave, and for whom such a condition is expedient and right, or rather is not all slavery a violation of nature? There is no difficulty in answering this question, on grounds both of reason and of fact. For that some should rule, and others be ruled is a thing not only necessary, but expedient”.
 
73
Sismondi (1819); Cardao-Pito (2021a, p. 264); Sowell (1972); Stewart (1984).
 
74
Sismondi (1819, pp.8–9): “Aristote, dans le premier livre de son Traité de la République a consacré quatre ou cinq chapitres (VIII à XIII) à la science qui nous occupe; il Hedonist theory emerges lui donne même un nom plus propre à la désigner que celui que nous avons adopté: (Chrématistique, gr χϱημαΤισΤικη), la Science des Richesses.”.
 
75
Sismondi (1819); Cardao-Pito (2021a, p. 264); Sowell (1972); Stewart (1984).
 
76
Buchbinder (1993); Cuban (2007); Starkey and Tiratsoo (2007);
 
77
Adapted from Aguinis et al. (2020); Gruber (2014); Moosa (2024), Cox et al. (2023)
 
78
Idem.
 
79
Idem.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abhayawansa, S., and S. Tyagi. 2021. Sustainable investing: The black box of environmental, social, and governance (ESG) ratings. The Journal of Wealth Management 24 (1): 49–54.CrossRef Abhayawansa, S., and S. Tyagi. 2021. Sustainable investing: The black box of environmental, social, and governance (ESG) ratings. The Journal of Wealth Management 24 (1): 49–54.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Adler, P.S., L.C. Forbes, and H. Willmott. 2007. 3 Critical management studies. The Academy of Management Annals 1 (1): 119–179.CrossRef Adler, P.S., L.C. Forbes, and H. Willmott. 2007. 3 Critical management studies. The Academy of Management Annals 1 (1): 119–179.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Adorno, T. 1965, 2001. Metaphysics: Concept and problems. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Adorno, T. 1965, 2001. Metaphysics: Concept and problems. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Aguinis, H., C. Cummings, R.S. Ramani, and T.G. Cummings. 2020. “An A is an A”: The new bottom line for valuing academic research. Academy of Management Perspectives 34 (1): 135–154.CrossRef Aguinis, H., C. Cummings, R.S. Ramani, and T.G. Cummings. 2020. “An A is an A”: The new bottom line for valuing academic research. Academy of Management Perspectives 34 (1): 135–154.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ahrne, G., and N. Brunsson, eds. 2019. Organization outside organizations: The abundance of partial organization in social life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ahrne, G., and N. Brunsson, eds. 2019. Organization outside organizations: The abundance of partial organization in social life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Amengual, M., and T. Bartley. 2022. Global markets, corporate assurances, and the legitimacy of state intervention: Perceptions of distant labor and environmental problems. American Sociological Review 87 (3): 383–414.CrossRef Amengual, M., and T. Bartley. 2022. Global markets, corporate assurances, and the legitimacy of state intervention: Perceptions of distant labor and environmental problems. American Sociological Review 87 (3): 383–414.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arvidsson, S., and J. Dumay. 2022. Corporate ESG reporting quantity, quality and performance: Where to now for environmental policy and practice? Business Strategy and the Environment 31 (3): 1091–1110.CrossRef Arvidsson, S., and J. Dumay. 2022. Corporate ESG reporting quantity, quality and performance: Where to now for environmental policy and practice? Business Strategy and the Environment 31 (3): 1091–1110.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Awaysheh, A., R.A. Heron, T. Perry, and J.I. Wilson. 2020. On the relation between corporate social responsibility and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal 41 (6): 965–987.CrossRef Awaysheh, A., R.A. Heron, T. Perry, and J.I. Wilson. 2020. On the relation between corporate social responsibility and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal 41 (6): 965–987.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Azeem, M., M. Ahmed, S. Haider, and M. Sajjad. 2021. Expanding competitive advantage through organizational culture, knowledge sharing and organizational innovation. Technology in Society 66: 101635.CrossRef Azeem, M., M. Ahmed, S. Haider, and M. Sajjad. 2021. Expanding competitive advantage through organizational culture, knowledge sharing and organizational innovation. Technology in Society 66: 101635.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Backhouse, R. 2002. The penguin history of economics. London: Penguin. Backhouse, R. 2002. The penguin history of economics. London: Penguin.
Zurück zum Zitat Barnett, M.L. 2022. Stakeholders Shan’t save society. Organization Studies 43 (8): 1343–1346.CrossRef Barnett, M.L. 2022. Stakeholders Shan’t save society. Organization Studies 43 (8): 1343–1346.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17 (1): 99–120.CrossRef Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17 (1): 99–120.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barney, J.B. 1995. Looking inside for competitive advantage. Academy of Management Perspectives 9 (4): 49–61.CrossRef Barney, J.B. 1995. Looking inside for competitive advantage. Academy of Management Perspectives 9 (4): 49–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bauwens, T., M. Hekkert, and J. Kirchherr. 2020. Circular futures: What will they look like? Ecological Economics 175: 106703. Bauwens, T., M. Hekkert, and J. Kirchherr. 2020. Circular futures: What will they look like? Ecological Economics 175: 106703.
Zurück zum Zitat Bhar, S., S. Lele, and N.D. Rao. 2022. Beyond income: Correlates of conspicuous and luxury consumption in India. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 18 (1): 142–157. Bhar, S., S. Lele, and N.D. Rao. 2022. Beyond income: Correlates of conspicuous and luxury consumption in India. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 18 (1): 142–157.
Zurück zum Zitat Billinger, S., and M. Workiewicz. 2019. Fading hierarchies and the emergence of new forms of organization. Journal of Organization Design 8 (1): 1–6. Billinger, S., and M. Workiewicz. 2019. Fading hierarchies and the emergence of new forms of organization. Journal of Organization Design 8 (1): 1–6.
Zurück zum Zitat Blok, V. 2021. Ecological management: A research agenda: Guest editorial. Philosophy of Management 20 (1): 1–4.CrossRef Blok, V. 2021. Ecological management: A research agenda: Guest editorial. Philosophy of Management 20 (1): 1–4.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blomsma, F., and G. Brennan. 2017. The emergence of circular economy: A new framing around prolonging resource productivity. Journal of Industrial Ecology 21 (3): 603–614.CrossRef Blomsma, F., and G. Brennan. 2017. The emergence of circular economy: A new framing around prolonging resource productivity. Journal of Industrial Ecology 21 (3): 603–614.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blomsma, F., T. Bauwens, I. Weissbrod, and J. Kirchherr. 2023. The ‘need for speed’: Toward circular disruption—What it is, how to make it happen and how to know it’s happening. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (3): 1010–1031.CrossRef Blomsma, F., T. Bauwens, I. Weissbrod, and J. Kirchherr. 2023. The ‘need for speed’: Toward circular disruption—What it is, how to make it happen and how to know it’s happening. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (3): 1010–1031.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bocken, N., and T.H. Geradts. 2020. Barriers and drivers to sustainable business model innovation: Organization design and dynamic capabilities. Long Range Planning 53 (4): Article 101950.CrossRef Bocken, N., and T.H. Geradts. 2020. Barriers and drivers to sustainable business model innovation: Organization design and dynamic capabilities. Long Range Planning 53 (4): Article 101950.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bocken, N., and J. Konietzko. 2022. Circular business model innovation in consumer-facing corporations. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 185: Article 122076.CrossRef Bocken, N., and J. Konietzko. 2022. Circular business model innovation in consumer-facing corporations. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 185: Article 122076.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bocken, N.M., and S.W. Short. 2016. Toward a sufficiency-driven business model: Experiences and opportunities. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 18: 41–61.CrossRef Bocken, N.M., and S.W. Short. 2016. Toward a sufficiency-driven business model: Experiences and opportunities. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 18: 41–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bodin, Ö., S.M. Alexander, J. Baggio, M.L. Barnes, R. Berardo, G.S. Cumming, L.E. Dee, A.P. Fischer, M. Fischer, M. Mancilla Garcia, and A.M. Guerrero. 2019. Improving network approaches to the study of complex social–ecological interdependencies. Nature Sustainability 2 (7): 551–559.CrossRef Bodin, Ö., S.M. Alexander, J. Baggio, M.L. Barnes, R. Berardo, G.S. Cumming, L.E. Dee, A.P. Fischer, M. Fischer, M. Mancilla Garcia, and A.M. Guerrero. 2019. Improving network approaches to the study of complex social–ecological interdependencies. Nature Sustainability 2 (7): 551–559.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boudreaux, D.J., and R. Meiners. 2019. Externality: Origins and classifications. Natural Resources Journal 59: 1. Boudreaux, D.J., and R. Meiners. 2019. Externality: Origins and classifications. Natural Resources Journal 59: 1.
Zurück zum Zitat Bowden, B. 2021. The historic (wrong) turn in management and organizational studies. Journal of Management History 27 (1): 8–27.CrossRef Bowden, B. 2021. The historic (wrong) turn in management and organizational studies. Journal of Management History 27 (1): 8–27.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brooks, S., and A. Kumar. 2023. Why the super-rich will not be saving the world: Philanthropy and “privatization creep” in global development. Business & Society 62 (2): 223–228.CrossRef Brooks, S., and A. Kumar. 2023. Why the super-rich will not be saving the world: Philanthropy and “privatization creep” in global development. Business & Society 62 (2): 223–228.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchbinder, H. 1993. The market oriented university and the changing role of knowledge. Higher Education 26 (3): 331–347.CrossRef Buchbinder, H. 1993. The market oriented university and the changing role of knowledge. Higher Education 26 (3): 331–347.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burnyeat, M.F. 1976a. Protagoras and self-refutation in Plato’s Theaetetus. The Philosophical Review 85 (2): 172.CrossRef Burnyeat, M.F. 1976a. Protagoras and self-refutation in Plato’s Theaetetus. The Philosophical Review 85 (2): 172.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burnyeat, M.F. 1976b. Protagoras and self-refutation in later Greek Philosophy. Philosophical Review 85 (1): 44–69.CrossRef Burnyeat, M.F. 1976b. Protagoras and self-refutation in later Greek Philosophy. Philosophical Review 85 (1): 44–69.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cardao-Pito, Tiago. 2012. Intangible flow theory. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 71 (2): 328–353.CrossRef Cardao-Pito, Tiago. 2012. Intangible flow theory. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 71 (2): 328–353.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cardao-Pito, T. 2016. A law for the social sciences regarding us human beings. Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 28 (2): 202–229.CrossRef Cardao-Pito, T. 2016. A law for the social sciences regarding us human beings. Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 28 (2): 202–229.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cardao-Pito, T. 2017. Organizations as producers of operating product flows to members of society. SAGE Open 7 (3): 1–18 (July-September).CrossRef Cardao-Pito, T. 2017. Organizations as producers of operating product flows to members of society. SAGE Open 7 (3): 1–18 (July-September).CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cardao-Pito, T. 2021a. Intangible flow theory in economics: Human participation in economic and societal production. London: Routledge. Cardao-Pito, T. 2021a. Intangible flow theory in economics: Human participation in economic and societal production. London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Cardao-Pito, T. 2021b. Fisher-Modigliani-Miller organisational finance theory and the financialisation of contemporary societies. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 28 (4): 499–522.CrossRef Cardao-Pito, T. 2021b. Fisher-Modigliani-Miller organisational finance theory and the financialisation of contemporary societies. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 28 (4): 499–522.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cardao-Pito, T., J.A. Smith, and J.S. Ferreira. 2021c. Using accounting measures of (in)tangibility for organizational classifications. Quantitative Finance and Economics 5 (2): 325–351.CrossRef Cardao-Pito, T., J.A. Smith, and J.S. Ferreira. 2021c. Using accounting measures of (in)tangibility for organizational classifications. Quantitative Finance and Economics 5 (2): 325–351.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Castro, G., and H. Lopes. 2024. The sky is the limit: Evaluating business models from an integral and non-reductionist view of reality. Philosophy of Management:1–27. Castro, G., and H. Lopes. 2024. The sky is the limit: Evaluating business models from an integral and non-reductionist view of reality. Philosophy of Management:1–27.
Zurück zum Zitat Centobelli, P., R. Cerchione, D. Chiaroni, P. Del Vecchio, and A. Urbinati. 2020. Designing business models in circular economy: A systematic literature review and research agenda. Business Strategy and the Environment 29: 1734–1749.CrossRef Centobelli, P., R. Cerchione, D. Chiaroni, P. Del Vecchio, and A. Urbinati. 2020. Designing business models in circular economy: A systematic literature review and research agenda. Business Strategy and the Environment 29: 1734–1749.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chedrak, C., G. Paulin, and J. Rajaonson. 2023. A fine wine, better with age: Circular economy historical roots and influential publications: A bibliometric analysis using Reference Publication Year Spectroscopy (RPYS). Journal of Industrial Ecology 27(6): 1593–1612. Chedrak, C., G. Paulin, and J. Rajaonson. 2023. A fine wine, better with age: Circular economy historical roots and influential publications: A bibliometric analysis using Reference Publication Year Spectroscopy (RPYS). Journal of Industrial Ecology 27(6): 1593–1612.
Zurück zum Zitat Christensen, C.M. 2001. Competitive advantage. MIT Sloan Management Review 42 (2): 105–109. Christensen, C.M. 2001. Competitive advantage. MIT Sloan Management Review 42 (2): 105–109.
Zurück zum Zitat Clark, C.E., M. Riera, and M. Iborra. 2022. Toward a theoretical framework of corporate social irresponsibility: Clarifying the gray zones between responsibility and irresponsibility. Business & Society 61 (6): 1473–1511.CrossRef Clark, C.E., M. Riera, and M. Iborra. 2022. Toward a theoretical framework of corporate social irresponsibility: Clarifying the gray zones between responsibility and irresponsibility. Business & Society 61 (6): 1473–1511.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clegg, S., J. Schweitzer, A. Whittle, and C. Pitelis. 2020. Strategy: Theory and practice, 3rd ed. Glasgow: SAGE. Clegg, S., J. Schweitzer, A. Whittle, and C. Pitelis. 2020. Strategy: Theory and practice, 3rd ed. Glasgow: SAGE.
Zurück zum Zitat Cohen, M. A. 2023. Reconstructing the moral logic of the stakeholder approach, and reconsidering the participation requirement. Philosophy of Management:1–16. Cohen, M. A. 2023. Reconstructing the moral logic of the stakeholder approach, and reconsidering the participation requirement. Philosophy of Management:1–16.
Zurück zum Zitat Cort, T., and D. Esty. 2020. ESG standards: Looming challenges and pathways forward. Organization & Environment 33 (4): 491–510.CrossRef Cort, T., and D. Esty. 2020. ESG standards: Looming challenges and pathways forward. Organization & Environment 33 (4): 491–510.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Corvellec, H., S. Böhm, A. Stowell, and F. Valenzuela. 2020. Introduction to the special issue on the contested realities of the circular economy. Culture and Organization 26: 97–102.CrossRef Corvellec, H., S. Böhm, A. Stowell, and F. Valenzuela. 2020. Introduction to the special issue on the contested realities of the circular economy. Culture and Organization 26: 97–102.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Corvellec, H., A.F. Stowell, and N. Johansson. 2022. Critiques of the circular economy. Journal of Industrial Ecology 26 (2): 421–432.CrossRef Corvellec, H., A.F. Stowell, and N. Johansson. 2022. Critiques of the circular economy. Journal of Industrial Ecology 26 (2): 421–432.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, D., J. Boaks, and M. P. Levine. 2023. Integrity and the University. Philosophy of Management:1–16. Cox, D., J. Boaks, and M. P. Levine. 2023. Integrity and the University. Philosophy of Management:1–16.
Zurück zum Zitat Coyne, K.P. 1986. Sustainable competitive advantage – What it is, what it isn’t. Business Horizons 29 (1): 54–61.CrossRef Coyne, K.P. 1986. Sustainable competitive advantage – What it is, what it isn’t. Business Horizons 29 (1): 54–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crace, L., and J. Gehman. 2023. What really explains ESG performance? Disentangling the asymmetrical drivers of the triple bottom line. Organization & Environment 36 (1): 150–178.CrossRef Crace, L., and J. Gehman. 2023. What really explains ESG performance? Disentangling the asymmetrical drivers of the triple bottom line. Organization & Environment 36 (1): 150–178.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cuban, L. 2007. The blackboard and the bottom line: Why schools can’t be businesses. Boston: Harvard University Press.CrossRef Cuban, L. 2007. The blackboard and the bottom line: Why schools can’t be businesses. Boston: Harvard University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat D’Itria, E., and R. Aus. 2023. Circular fashion: evolving practices in a changing industry. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 19 (1): 2220592. D’Itria, E., and R. Aus. 2023. Circular fashion: evolving practices in a changing industry. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 19 (1): 2220592.
Zurück zum Zitat Dagnino, G.B., P.M. Picone, and G. Ferrigno. 2021. Temporary competitive advantage: A state-of-the-art literature review and research directions. International Journal of Management Reviews 23 (1): 85–115.CrossRef Dagnino, G.B., P.M. Picone, and G. Ferrigno. 2021. Temporary competitive advantage: A state-of-the-art literature review and research directions. International Journal of Management Reviews 23 (1): 85–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, G.F. 2016. Organization theory and the dilemmas of a post-corporate economy. In How institutions matter! 311–322. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Davis, G.F. 2016. Organization theory and the dilemmas of a post-corporate economy. In How institutions matter! 311–322. Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Zurück zum Zitat De Angelis, R., and G. Ianulardo. 2020. Circular economy as fictional expectation to overcome societal addictions. Where do we stand? Philosophy of Management 19 (2): 133–153.CrossRef De Angelis, R., and G. Ianulardo. 2020. Circular economy as fictional expectation to overcome societal addictions. Where do we stand? Philosophy of Management 19 (2): 133–153.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Bakker, F.G.A., D. Matten, L.J. Spence, and C. Wickert. 2020. The elephant in the room: The nascent research agenda on corporations, social responsibility, and capitalism. Business & Society 59: 1295–1302.CrossRef De Bakker, F.G.A., D. Matten, L.J. Spence, and C. Wickert. 2020. The elephant in the room: The nascent research agenda on corporations, social responsibility, and capitalism. Business & Society 59: 1295–1302.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deem, R., and K.J. Brehony. 2005. Management as ideology: The case of ‘new managerialism’ in higher education. Oxford Review of Education 31 (2): 217–235.CrossRef Deem, R., and K.J. Brehony. 2005. Management as ideology: The case of ‘new managerialism’ in higher education. Oxford Review of Education 31 (2): 217–235.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dentoni, D., J. Pinkse, and R. Lubberink. 2021. Linking sustainable business models to socio-ecological resilience through cross-sector partnerships: A complex adaptive systems view. Business & Society 60 (5): 1216–1252.CrossRef Dentoni, D., J. Pinkse, and R. Lubberink. 2021. Linking sustainable business models to socio-ecological resilience through cross-sector partnerships: A complex adaptive systems view. Business & Society 60 (5): 1216–1252.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat DiVito, L., E. Leitheiser, and C. Piller. 2022. Circular moonshot: Understanding shifts in organizational field logics and business model innovation. Organization & Environment 36(2): 349–377. DiVito, L., E. Leitheiser, and C. Piller. 2022. Circular moonshot: Understanding shifts in organizational field logics and business model innovation. Organization & Environment 36(2): 349–377.
Zurück zum Zitat Drakopoulos, S.A. 2024. Value judgements, positivism and utility comparisons in economics. Journal of Business Ethics 189 (3): 423–437.CrossRef Drakopoulos, S.A. 2024. Value judgements, positivism and utility comparisons in economics. Journal of Business Ethics 189 (3): 423–437.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Droege, H., J. Kirchherr, A. Raggi, and T.B. Ramos. 2023. Toward a circular disruption: On the pivotal role of circular economy policy entrepreneurs. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (3): 1142–1158.CrossRef Droege, H., J. Kirchherr, A. Raggi, and T.B. Ramos. 2023. Toward a circular disruption: On the pivotal role of circular economy policy entrepreneurs. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (3): 1142–1158.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dupont, B. 2017. The history of economic ideas: Economic thought in contemporary context. Oxon: Routledge.CrossRef Dupont, B. 2017. The history of economic ideas: Economic thought in contemporary context. Oxon: Routledge.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dzhengiz, T., E.M. Miller, J.P. Ovaska, and S. Patala. 2023. Unpacking the circular economy: A problematizing review. International Journal of Management Reviews. 25: 270–296.CrossRef Dzhengiz, T., E.M. Miller, J.P. Ovaska, and S. Patala. 2023. Unpacking the circular economy: A problematizing review. International Journal of Management Reviews. 25: 270–296.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eikelenboom, M., and G. de Jong. 2022. The impact of managers and network interactions on the integration of circularity in business strategy. Organization & Environment 35 (3): 365–393.CrossRef Eikelenboom, M., and G. de Jong. 2022. The impact of managers and network interactions on the integration of circularity in business strategy. Organization & Environment 35 (3): 365–393.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eppinger, E. 2022. Recycling technologies for enabling sustainability transitions of the fashion industry: Status quo and avenues for increasing post-consumer waste recycling. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 18 (1): 114–128. Eppinger, E. 2022. Recycling technologies for enabling sustainability transitions of the fashion industry: Status quo and avenues for increasing post-consumer waste recycling. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 18 (1): 114–128.
Zurück zum Zitat Fassin, Y. 2009. The stakeholder model refined. Journal of Business Ethics 84 (1): 113–135.CrossRef Fassin, Y. 2009. The stakeholder model refined. Journal of Business Ethics 84 (1): 113–135.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feger, C., and L. Mermet. 2022. New business models for biodiversity and ecosystem management services: Action research with a large environmental sector company. Organization and Environment 35 (2): 252–281.CrossRef Feger, C., and L. Mermet. 2022. New business models for biodiversity and ecosystem management services: Action research with a large environmental sector company. Organization and Environment 35 (2): 252–281.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferasso, M., T. Beliaeva, S. Kraus, T. Clauss, and D. Ribeiro-Soriano. 2020. Circular economy business models: The state of research and avenues ahead. Business Strategy and the Environment 29 (8): 3006–3024.CrossRef Ferasso, M., T. Beliaeva, S. Kraus, T. Clauss, and D. Ribeiro-Soriano. 2020. Circular economy business models: The state of research and avenues ahead. Business Strategy and the Environment 29 (8): 3006–3024.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferraro, F., D. Etzion, and J. Gehman. 2015. Tackling grand challenges pragmatically: Robust action revisited. Organization Studies 36 (3): 363–390.CrossRef Ferraro, F., D. Etzion, and J. Gehman. 2015. Tackling grand challenges pragmatically: Robust action revisited. Organization Studies 36 (3): 363–390.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Figge, F., A.S. Thorpe, and S. Manzhynski. 2022. Value creation and the circular economy: A tale of three externalities. Journal of Industrial Ecology 26 (5): 1690–1700.CrossRef Figge, F., A.S. Thorpe, and S. Manzhynski. 2022. Value creation and the circular economy: A tale of three externalities. Journal of Industrial Ecology 26 (5): 1690–1700.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Flammer, C. 2015. Does product market competition foster corporate social responsibility? Evidence from trade liberalization. Strategic Management Journal 36 (10): 1469–1485.CrossRef Flammer, C. 2015. Does product market competition foster corporate social responsibility? Evidence from trade liberalization. Strategic Management Journal 36 (10): 1469–1485.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman, R., A. Wicks, and B. Parmar. 2004. Stakeholder theory and “the corporate objective revisited. Organization Science 15 (3): 364–369.CrossRef Freeman, R., A. Wicks, and B. Parmar. 2004. Stakeholder theory and “the corporate objective revisited. Organization Science 15 (3): 364–369.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman, R.E., K. Martin, and B. Parmar. 2007. Stakeholder capitalism. Journal of Business Ethics 74 (4): 303–314.CrossRef Freeman, R.E., K. Martin, and B. Parmar. 2007. Stakeholder capitalism. Journal of Business Ethics 74 (4): 303–314.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman, R.E., S.D. Dmytriyev, and R.A. Phillips. 2021. Stakeholder theory and the resource-based view of the firm. Journal of Management 47 (7): 1757–1770.CrossRef Freeman, R.E., S.D. Dmytriyev, and R.A. Phillips. 2021. Stakeholder theory and the resource-based view of the firm. Journal of Management 47 (7): 1757–1770.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frei, R., L. Jack, and S.A. Krzyzaniak. 2020. Sustainable reverse supply chains and circular economy in multichannel retail returns. Business Strategy and the Environment 29: 1925–1940.CrossRef Frei, R., L. Jack, and S.A. Krzyzaniak. 2020. Sustainable reverse supply chains and circular economy in multichannel retail returns. Business Strategy and the Environment 29: 1925–1940.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, M. 1953. The methodology of positive economics. In Essays in positive economics, ed. M. Friedman. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Friedman, M. 1953. The methodology of positive economics. In Essays in positive economics, ed. M. Friedman. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, M. 1970. The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine, September, vol. 13, pp. 1970. Friedman, M. 1970. The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine, September, vol. 13, pp. 1970.
Zurück zum Zitat Frishammar, J., and V. Parida. 2019. Circular business model transformation: A roadmap for incumbent firms. California Management Review 61 (2): 5–29.CrossRef Frishammar, J., and V. Parida. 2019. Circular business model transformation: A roadmap for incumbent firms. California Management Review 61 (2): 5–29.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gao, Y., Y. Nie, and T. Hafsi. forthcoming. Not all stakeholders are equal: Corporate social responsibility variability and corporate financial performance. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility. Gao, Y., Y. Nie, and T. Hafsi. forthcoming. Not all stakeholders are equal: Corporate social responsibility variability and corporate financial performance. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility.
Zurück zum Zitat Garcia-Quevedo, J., E. Jove-Llopis, and E. Martinez-Ros. 2019. Barriers to the circular economy in European small and medium-sized firms. Business Strategy and the Environment 29: 2450–2464.CrossRef Garcia-Quevedo, J., E. Jove-Llopis, and E. Martinez-Ros. 2019. Barriers to the circular economy in European small and medium-sized firms. Business Strategy and the Environment 29: 2450–2464.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gare, A. 2013. Ethics, economics and civilization: Why a New metaphysics and a new socio-economic order are required to rescue ethics? Chromatikon 9 (IX): 121–145. Gare, A. 2013. Ethics, economics and civilization: Why a New metaphysics and a new socio-economic order are required to rescue ethics? Chromatikon 9 (IX): 121–145.
Zurück zum Zitat Gartenberg, C., A. Prat, and G. Serafeim. 2019. Corporate purpose and financial performance. Organization Science 30 (1): 1–18.CrossRef Gartenberg, C., A. Prat, and G. Serafeim. 2019. Corporate purpose and financial performance. Organization Science 30 (1): 1–18.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Geng, Y., J. Sarkis, and R. Bleischwitz. 2019. How to globalize the circular economy. Nature 565: 153–155.CrossRef Geng, Y., J. Sarkis, and R. Bleischwitz. 2019. How to globalize the circular economy. Nature 565: 153–155.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat George, G., S.J. Schillebeeckx, and T.L. Liak. 2015. The management of natural resources: An overview and research agenda. Academy of Management Journal 58 (6): 1595–1613.CrossRef George, G., S.J. Schillebeeckx, and T.L. Liak. 2015. The management of natural resources: An overview and research agenda. Academy of Management Journal 58 (6): 1595–1613.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat George, G., J. Howard-Grenville, A. Joshi, and L. Tihanyi. 2016. Understanding and tackling societal grand challenges through management research. Academy of Management Journal 59 (6): 1880–1895.CrossRef George, G., J. Howard-Grenville, A. Joshi, and L. Tihanyi. 2016. Understanding and tackling societal grand challenges through management research. Academy of Management Journal 59 (6): 1880–1895.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat George, G., M. R. Haas, A. M. McGahan, S. J. D. Schillebeeckx, and P. Tracey. 2021. Purpose in the for-profit firm: A review and framework for management research. Journal of Management 49 (6): 1841–1869. George, G., M. R. Haas, A. M. McGahan, S. J. D. Schillebeeckx, and P. Tracey. 2021. Purpose in the for-profit firm: A review and framework for management research. Journal of Management 49 (6): 1841–1869.
Zurück zum Zitat Ghisellini, P., C. Cialani, and S. Ulgiati. 2016. A review on circular economy: The expected transition to a balanced interplay of environmental and economic systems. Journal of Cleaner Production 114: 11–32.CrossRef Ghisellini, P., C. Cialani, and S. Ulgiati. 2016. A review on circular economy: The expected transition to a balanced interplay of environmental and economic systems. Journal of Cleaner Production 114: 11–32.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gibson, K. 2000. The moral basis of stakeholder theory. Journal of Business Ethics 26 (3): 245–257.CrossRef Gibson, K. 2000. The moral basis of stakeholder theory. Journal of Business Ethics 26 (3): 245–257.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Glavas, A., and J. Mish. 2015. Resources and capabilities of triple bottom line firms: Going over old or breaking new ground? Journal of Business Ethics 127 (3): 623–642.CrossRef Glavas, A., and J. Mish. 2015. Resources and capabilities of triple bottom line firms: Going over old or breaking new ground? Journal of Business Ethics 127 (3): 623–642.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gooch, P.W. 2000. Plato on philosophy and money. Philosophy in the Contemporary World 7 (4): 13–20.CrossRef Gooch, P.W. 2000. Plato on philosophy and money. Philosophy in the Contemporary World 7 (4): 13–20.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goodell, G.S. 1972. Social responsibility and the profit motive. Business & Society 13 (1): 23–27.CrossRef Goodell, G.S. 1972. Social responsibility and the profit motive. Business & Society 13 (1): 23–27.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gray, B.H. 1991. The profit motive and patient care: The changing accountability of doctors and hospitals. Boston: Harvard University Press. Gray, B.H. 1991. The profit motive and patient care: The changing accountability of doctors and hospitals. Boston: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gruber, T. 2014. Academic sell-out: How an obsession with metrics and rankings is damaging academia. Journal of Marketing for Higher Education 24 (2): 165–177.CrossRef Gruber, T. 2014. Academic sell-out: How an obsession with metrics and rankings is damaging academia. Journal of Marketing for Higher Education 24 (2): 165–177.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hahn, T., and J. Pinkse. 2022. A paradox approach to sustainable product-service systems. Industrial Marketing Management 105: 182–189.CrossRef Hahn, T., and J. Pinkse. 2022. A paradox approach to sustainable product-service systems. Industrial Marketing Management 105: 182–189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hassard, J. 1999. Postmodernism, philosophy and management: Concepts and controversies. International Journal of Management Reviews 1 (2): 171–195.CrossRef Hassard, J. 1999. Postmodernism, philosophy and management: Concepts and controversies. International Journal of Management Reviews 1 (2): 171–195.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat He, Y., and R. Chittoor. 2022. When does it (not) pay to be good? Interplay between stakeholder and competitive strategies. Journal of Management 49 (7): 2490–2522. He, Y., and R. Chittoor. 2022. When does it (not) pay to be good? Interplay between stakeholder and competitive strategies. Journal of Management 49 (7): 2490–2522.
Zurück zum Zitat Hecht, A.D., J. Fiksel, S.C. Fulton, T.F. Yosie, N.C. Hawkins, H. Leuenberger, J.S. Golden, and T.E. Lovejoy. 2012. Creating the future we want. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 8 (2): 62–75. Hecht, A.D., J. Fiksel, S.C. Fulton, T.F. Yosie, N.C. Hawkins, H. Leuenberger, J.S. Golden, and T.E. Lovejoy. 2012. Creating the future we want. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 8 (2): 62–75.
Zurück zum Zitat Heikkurinen, P., T. Ruuska, A. Kuokkanen, and S. Russell. 2021. Leaving productivism behind: Towards a holistic and processual philosophy of ecological management. Philosophy of Management 20: 21–36.CrossRef Heikkurinen, P., T. Ruuska, A. Kuokkanen, and S. Russell. 2021. Leaving productivism behind: Towards a holistic and processual philosophy of ecological management. Philosophy of Management 20: 21–36.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hiquet, R., C. Wordley, and S. Ansari. 2023. Why does faithful epistemic representation matter for management practices? The case of the natural environment in management theory. Philosophy of Management 22 (3): 347–372. Hiquet, R., C. Wordley, and S. Ansari. 2023. Why does faithful epistemic representation matter for management practices? The case of the natural environment in management theory. Philosophy of Management 22 (3): 347–372.
Zurück zum Zitat Ho, J., C. Lu, and L. Lucianetti. 2021. Does engaging in corporate social responsibility activities influence firm performance? The moderating effects of risk preferences and performance measurement systems. Management Decision 59 (13): 15–37.CrossRef Ho, J., C. Lu, and L. Lucianetti. 2021. Does engaging in corporate social responsibility activities influence firm performance? The moderating effects of risk preferences and performance measurement systems. Management Decision 59 (13): 15–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Howard-Grenville, J., G.F. Davis, T. Dyllick, C.C. Miller, S. Thau, and A. Tsui. 2019. Sustainable development for a better world: Contributions of leadership, management, and organizations. Academy of Management Discoveries 5 (4): 355–366. Howard-Grenville, J., G.F. Davis, T. Dyllick, C.C. Miller, S. Thau, and A. Tsui. 2019. Sustainable development for a better world: Contributions of leadership, management, and organizations. Academy of Management Discoveries 5 (4): 355–366.
Zurück zum Zitat Hühn, M.P., and M. Meyer. 2023. Sophistry or wisdom in words: Aristotle on rhetoric and leadership. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 32 (2): 544–554.CrossRef Hühn, M.P., and M. Meyer. 2023. Sophistry or wisdom in words: Aristotle on rhetoric and leadership. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 32 (2): 544–554.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobides, M.G., C. Cennamo, and A. Gawer. 2018. Towards a theory of ecosystems. Strategic Management Journal 39 (8): 2255–2276. Jacobides, M.G., C. Cennamo, and A. Gawer. 2018. Towards a theory of ecosystems. Strategic Management Journal 39 (8): 2255–2276.
Zurück zum Zitat Jamali, D., R. Barkemeyer, G. Samara, and S. Markovic. 2022. The SDGs: A change agenda shaping the future of business and humanity at large. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 31 (4): 899–903.CrossRef Jamali, D., R. Barkemeyer, G. Samara, and S. Markovic. 2022. The SDGs: A change agenda shaping the future of business and humanity at large. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 31 (4): 899–903.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jammulamadaka, N., A. Faria, G. Jack, and S. Ruggunan. 2021. Decolonising management and organisational knowledge (MOK): Praxistical theorising for potential worlds. Organization 28 (5): 717–740.CrossRef Jammulamadaka, N., A. Faria, G. Jack, and S. Ruggunan. 2021. Decolonising management and organisational knowledge (MOK): Praxistical theorising for potential worlds. Organization 28 (5): 717–740.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Josifidis, K., and N. Supic. 2021. (Are) institutions more important than innovation? Journal of Economic Issues 55 (2): 334–341. Josifidis, K., and N. Supic. 2021. (Are) institutions more important than innovation? Journal of Economic Issues 55 (2): 334–341.
Zurück zum Zitat Kapil, S., and V. Rawal. forthcoming. Sustainable investment and environmental, social, and governance investing: A bibliometric and systematic literature review. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 32 (4): 1429–1451. Kapil, S., and V. Rawal. forthcoming. Sustainable investment and environmental, social, and governance investing: A bibliometric and systematic literature review. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 32 (4): 1429–1451.
Zurück zum Zitat Kapoor, R. 2018. Ecosystems: broadening the locus of value creation. Journal of Organization Design 7 (1): 1–16. Kapoor, R. 2018. Ecosystems: broadening the locus of value creation. Journal of Organization Design 7 (1): 1–16.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaul, A., and J. Luo. 2018. An economic case for CSR: The comparative efficiency of for-profit firms in meeting consumer demand for social goods. Strategic Management Journal 39 (6): 1650–1677. Kaul, A., and J. Luo. 2018. An economic case for CSR: The comparative efficiency of for-profit firms in meeting consumer demand for social goods. Strategic Management Journal 39 (6): 1650–1677.
Zurück zum Zitat Kirchherr, J., D. Reike, and M. Hekkert. 2017. Conceptualizing the circular economy: An analysis of 114 definitions. Resources, conservation and recycling 127: 221–232. Kirchherr, J., D. Reike, and M. Hekkert. 2017. Conceptualizing the circular economy: An analysis of 114 definitions. Resources, conservation and recycling 127: 221–232.
Zurück zum Zitat Kirchherr, J., A. Urbinati, and K. Hartley. 2023. Circular economy: A new research field?. Journal of Industrial Ecology 27 (5): 1239–1251. Kirchherr, J., A. Urbinati, and K. Hartley. 2023. Circular economy: A new research field?. Journal of Industrial Ecology 27 (5): 1239–1251.
Zurück zum Zitat Kjaer, L.L., D.C. Pigosso, M. Niero, N.M. Bech, and T.C. McAloone. 2019. Product/service-systems for a circular economy: The route to decoupling economic growth from resource consumption? Journal of Industrial Ecology 23: 22–35.CrossRef Kjaer, L.L., D.C. Pigosso, M. Niero, N.M. Bech, and T.C. McAloone. 2019. Product/service-systems for a circular economy: The route to decoupling economic growth from resource consumption? Journal of Industrial Ecology 23: 22–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kopnina, H. 2021. Towards ecological management: Identifying barriers and opportunities in transition from linear to circular economy. Philosophy of Management 20 (1): 5–19.CrossRef Kopnina, H. 2021. Towards ecological management: Identifying barriers and opportunities in transition from linear to circular economy. Philosophy of Management 20 (1): 5–19.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kukla, A. 2000. Social constructivism and the philosophy of science. New York: Routledge. Kukla, A. 2000. Social constructivism and the philosophy of science. New York: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Kunisch, S., D. zu Knyphausen-Aufsess, H. Bapuji, H. Aguinis, P. T. Bansal, A. S. Tsui, and J. Pinto. 2020. Call for special issue papers on “Grand societal challenges: The contributions of business, management and organisation studies.” International Journal of Management Reviews. Kunisch, S., D. zu Knyphausen-Aufsess, H. Bapuji, H. Aguinis, P. T. Bansal, A. S. Tsui, and J. Pinto. 2020. Call for special issue papers on “Grand societal challenges: The contributions of business, management and organisation studies.” International Journal of Management Reviews.
Zurück zum Zitat Kurucz, E., B. Colbert, and J. Marcus. 2014. Sustainability as a provocation to rethink management education: Building a progressive educative practice. Management Learning 45 (4): 437–457.CrossRef Kurucz, E., B. Colbert, and J. Marcus. 2014. Sustainability as a provocation to rethink management education: Building a progressive educative practice. Management Learning 45 (4): 437–457.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lane, J.E. 2002. New public management: An introduction. New York: Routledge.CrossRef Lane, J.E. 2002. New public management: An introduction. New York: Routledge.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Laplume, A., K. Sonpar, and R. Litz. 2008. Stakeholder theory: Reviewing a theory that moves us. Journal of Management 34 (6): 1152–1189.CrossRef Laplume, A., K. Sonpar, and R. Litz. 2008. Stakeholder theory: Reviewing a theory that moves us. Journal of Management 34 (6): 1152–1189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Latapí Agudelo, M.A., L. Jóhannsdóttir, and B. Davídsdóttir. 2019. A literature review of the history and evolution of corporate social responsibility. International Journal of Corporate Social Responsibility 4 (1): 1–23.CrossRef Latapí Agudelo, M.A., L. Jóhannsdóttir, and B. Davídsdóttir. 2019. A literature review of the history and evolution of corporate social responsibility. International Journal of Corporate Social Responsibility 4 (1): 1–23.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, M. 2005. Epistemology after protagoras: Responses to relativism in Plato, Aristotle, and Democritus. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Lee, M. 2005. Epistemology after protagoras: Responses to relativism in Plato, Aristotle, and Democritus. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leipold, S., A. Petit-Boix, A. Luo, H. Helander, M. Simoens, W.S. Ashton, C.W. Babbitt, A. Bala, C.R. Bening, M. Birkved, and F. Blomsma. 2023. Lessons, narratives, and research directions for a sustainable circular economy. Journal of Industrial Ecology 27 (1): 6–18.CrossRef Leipold, S., A. Petit-Boix, A. Luo, H. Helander, M. Simoens, W.S. Ashton, C.W. Babbitt, A. Bala, C.R. Bening, M. Birkved, and F. Blomsma. 2023. Lessons, narratives, and research directions for a sustainable circular economy. Journal of Industrial Ecology 27 (1): 6–18.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lemaire, A., and S. Limbourg. 2019. How can food loss and waste management achieve sustainable development goals? Journal of Cleaner Production 234: 1221–1234.CrossRef Lemaire, A., and S. Limbourg. 2019. How can food loss and waste management achieve sustainable development goals? Journal of Cleaner Production 234: 1221–1234.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lepak, D.P., and S.A. Snell. 1999. The human resource architecture: Toward a theory of human capital allocation and development. Academy of Management Review 24 (1): 31–48. Lepak, D.P., and S.A. Snell. 1999. The human resource architecture: Toward a theory of human capital allocation and development. Academy of Management Review 24 (1): 31–48.
Zurück zum Zitat Liebowitz, S.J., and S.E. Margolis. 1994. Network externality: An uncommon tragedy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8 (2): 133–150.CrossRef Liebowitz, S.J., and S.E. Margolis. 1994. Network externality: An uncommon tragedy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8 (2): 133–150.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lieder, M., and A. Rashid. 2016. Toward circular economy implementation: A comprehensive review in context of manufacturing industry. Journal of Cleaner Production 115: 36–51.CrossRef Lieder, M., and A. Rashid. 2016. Toward circular economy implementation: A comprehensive review in context of manufacturing industry. Journal of Cleaner Production 115: 36–51.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Linder, M., and M. Williander. 2017. Circular business model innovation: Inherent uncertainties. Business Strategy and the Environment 26 (2): 182–196.CrossRef Linder, M., and M. Williander. 2017. Circular business model innovation: Inherent uncertainties. Business Strategy and the Environment 26 (2): 182–196.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loux, M. 2008. Primary Ousia: An essay on Aristotle’s metaphysics Z and H. London: Cornell University Press.CrossRef Loux, M. 2008. Primary Ousia: An essay on Aristotle’s metaphysics Z and H. London: Cornell University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lüdeke-Freund, F., S. Carroux, A. Joyce, L. Massa, and H. Breuer. 2018. The sustainable business model pattern taxonomy—45 patterns to support sustainability-oriented business model innovation. Sustainable Production and Consumption 15: 145–162. Lüdeke-Freund, F., S. Carroux, A. Joyce, L. Massa, and H. Breuer. 2018. The sustainable business model pattern taxonomy—45 patterns to support sustainability-oriented business model innovation. Sustainable Production and Consumption 15: 145–162.
Zurück zum Zitat Lüdeke-Freund, F., S. Gold, and N.M. Bocken. 2019. A review and typology of circular economy business model patterns. Journal of Industrial Ecology 23 (1): 36–61.CrossRef Lüdeke-Freund, F., S. Gold, and N.M. Bocken. 2019. A review and typology of circular economy business model patterns. Journal of Industrial Ecology 23 (1): 36–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lux, K. 2003. The failure of the profit motive. Ecological Economics 44 (1): 1–9.CrossRef Lux, K. 2003. The failure of the profit motive. Ecological Economics 44 (1): 1–9.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lyotard, J.-F. (1984, 1997). The postmodern condition: A report on knowledge. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Lyotard, J.-F. (1984, 1997). The postmodern condition: A report on knowledge. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mahoney, J.T., and A.M. McGahan. 2007. The field of strategic management within the evolving science of strategic organization. Strategic Organization 5 (1): 79–99.CrossRef Mahoney, J.T., and A.M. McGahan. 2007. The field of strategic management within the evolving science of strategic organization. Strategic Organization 5 (1): 79–99.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mahoney, J.T., A.M. McGahan, and C.N. Pitelis. 2009. Perspective—The interdependence of private and public interests. Organization Science 20 (6): 1034–1052. Mahoney, J.T., A.M. McGahan, and C.N. Pitelis. 2009. Perspective—The interdependence of private and public interests. Organization Science 20 (6): 1034–1052.
Zurück zum Zitat Mahoney, J.T., and Y.Y. Kor. 2015. Advancing the human capital perspective on value creation by joining capabilities and governance approaches. Academy of Management Perspectives 29 (3): 296–308. Mahoney, J.T., and Y.Y. Kor. 2015. Advancing the human capital perspective on value creation by joining capabilities and governance approaches. Academy of Management Perspectives 29 (3): 296–308.
Zurück zum Zitat Mair, J., and N. Rathert. 2021. Alternative organizing with social purpose: Revisiting institutional analysis of market-based activity. Socio-Economic Review 19 (2): 817–836.CrossRef Mair, J., and N. Rathert. 2021. Alternative organizing with social purpose: Revisiting institutional analysis of market-based activity. Socio-Economic Review 19 (2): 817–836.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marcus, J., E. Kurucz, and B. Colbert. 2010. Conceptions of the business-society-nature interface: Implications for management scholarship”. Business and Society 49 (3): 402–438.CrossRef Marcus, J., E. Kurucz, and B. Colbert. 2010. Conceptions of the business-society-nature interface: Implications for management scholarship”. Business and Society 49 (3): 402–438.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Margolis, J., and J. Walsh. 2003. Misery loves companies: Rethinking social initiatives by business. Administrative Science Quarterly 48 (2): 268–305.CrossRef Margolis, J., and J. Walsh. 2003. Misery loves companies: Rethinking social initiatives by business. Administrative Science Quarterly 48 (2): 268–305.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marquis, C. 2020. Better business: How the B Corp movement is remaking capitalism. Yale University Press. Marquis, C. 2020. Better business: How the B Corp movement is remaking capitalism. Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mayer, C. 2021. The future of the corporation and the economics of purpose. Journal of Management Studies 58 (3): 887–901.CrossRef Mayer, C. 2021. The future of the corporation and the economics of purpose. Journal of Management Studies 58 (3): 887–901.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McCloskey, D.N. 2022. Beyond positivism, behaviorism, and neoinstitutionalism in economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef McCloskey, D.N. 2022. Beyond positivism, behaviorism, and neoinstitutionalism in economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGahan, A.M. 2021. Integrating insights from the resource-based view of the firm into the new stakeholder theory. Journal of Management 47 (7): 1734–1756.CrossRef McGahan, A.M. 2021. Integrating insights from the resource-based view of the firm into the new stakeholder theory. Journal of Management 47 (7): 1734–1756.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mikkelson, G.M. 2021. Invisible hand or ecological footprint? Comparing social versus environmental impacts of recent economic growth. Organization & Environment 34 (2): 287–297.CrossRef Mikkelson, G.M. 2021. Invisible hand or ecological footprint? Comparing social versus environmental impacts of recent economic growth. Organization & Environment 34 (2): 287–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moosa, I. 2024. Publish or perish: Perceived benefits versus unintended consequences, 2nd ed. London: Edward Elgar.CrossRef Moosa, I. 2024. Publish or perish: Perceived benefits versus unintended consequences, 2nd ed. London: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morseletto, P. 2023. Sometimes linear, sometimes circular: States of the economy and transitions to the future. Journal of Cleaner Production:136138. Morseletto, P. 2023. Sometimes linear, sometimes circular: States of the economy and transitions to the future. Journal of Cleaner Production:136138.
Zurück zum Zitat Neesham, C., K. Dembek, and J. Benkert.2023. Defining value in sustainable business models. Business & Society 62 (7): 1378–1419. Neesham, C., K. Dembek, and J. Benkert.2023. Defining value in sustainable business models. Business & Society 62 (7): 1378–1419.
Zurück zum Zitat Neligan, A., R.J. Baumgartner, M. Geissdoerfer, and J.-P. Schöggl. 2023. Circular disruption: Digitalisation as a driver of circular economy business models. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (3): 1175–1188.CrossRef Neligan, A., R.J. Baumgartner, M. Geissdoerfer, and J.-P. Schöggl. 2023. Circular disruption: Digitalisation as a driver of circular economy business models. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (3): 1175–1188.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Neves, S.A., and A.C. Marques. 2022. Drivers and barriers in the transition from a linear economy to a circular economy. Journal of Cleaner Production 341: 130865.CrossRef Neves, S.A., and A.C. Marques. 2022. Drivers and barriers in the transition from a linear economy to a circular economy. Journal of Cleaner Production 341: 130865.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Niero, M., C.L. Jensen, C.F. Fratini, J. Dorland, M.S. Jørgensen, and S. Georg. 2021. Is life cycle assessment enough to address unintended side effects from Circular Economy initiatives? Journal of Industrial Ecology 25 (5): 1111–1120.CrossRef Niero, M., C.L. Jensen, C.F. Fratini, J. Dorland, M.S. Jørgensen, and S. Georg. 2021. Is life cycle assessment enough to address unintended side effects from Circular Economy initiatives? Journal of Industrial Ecology 25 (5): 1111–1120.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Norris, C. 1997. Against relativism: Philosophy of science, deconstruction and critical theory. Oxford: Basil-Blackwell. Norris, C. 1997. Against relativism: Philosophy of science, deconstruction and critical theory. Oxford: Basil-Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Norris, L. 2019. Urban prototypes: Growing local circular cloth economies. Business History 61: 205–224.CrossRef Norris, L. 2019. Urban prototypes: Growing local circular cloth economies. Business History 61: 205–224.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nyberg, D., and C. Wright. 2016. Performative and political: Corporate constructions of climate change risk. Organization 23 (5): 617–638.CrossRef Nyberg, D., and C. Wright. 2016. Performative and political: Corporate constructions of climate change risk. Organization 23 (5): 617–638.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nyberg, D., G. Ferns, S. Vachhani, and C. Wright. 2022. Climate change, business, and society: Building relevance in time and space. Business & Society 61 (5): 1322–1352.CrossRef Nyberg, D., G. Ferns, S. Vachhani, and C. Wright. 2022. Climate change, business, and society: Building relevance in time and space. Business & Society 61 (5): 1322–1352.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Obel, B., and P. Kallehave. 2022. Designing a sustainable organization: the four I’s framework. Journal of Organization Design 11 (2): 65–76. Obel, B., and P. Kallehave. 2022. Designing a sustainable organization: the four I’s framework. Journal of Organization Design 11 (2): 65–76.
Zurück zum Zitat Okafor, A., B.N. Adeleye, and M. Adusei. 2021. Corporate social responsibility and financial performance: Evidence from US tech firms. Journal of Cleaner Production 292: 126078.CrossRef Okafor, A., B.N. Adeleye, and M. Adusei. 2021. Corporate social responsibility and financial performance: Evidence from US tech firms. Journal of Cleaner Production 292: 126078.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Owen, J.R., R. Zhang, and A. Arratia-Solar. 2020. On the economics of project-induced displacement: A critique of the externality principle in resource development projects. Journal of Cleaner Production 276: 123247.CrossRef Owen, J.R., R. Zhang, and A. Arratia-Solar. 2020. On the economics of project-induced displacement: A critique of the externality principle in resource development projects. Journal of Cleaner Production 276: 123247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Painter-Morland, M. 2015. Philosophical assumptions undermining responsible management education. Journal of Management Development 34 (1): 61–75.CrossRef Painter-Morland, M. 2015. Philosophical assumptions undermining responsible management education. Journal of Management Development 34 (1): 61–75.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Panwar, R., H. Ober, and J. Pinkse. 2022. The uncomfortable relationship between business and biodiversity: Advancing research on business strategies for biodiversity protection. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (5): 2554–2566. Panwar, R., H. Ober, and J. Pinkse. 2022. The uncomfortable relationship between business and biodiversity: Advancing research on business strategies for biodiversity protection. Business Strategy and the Environment 32 (5): 2554–2566.
Zurück zum Zitat Parida, V., T. Burström, I. Visnjic, and J. Wincent. 2019. Orchestrating industrial ecosystem in circular economy: A two-stage transformation model for large manufacturing companies. Journal of Business Research 101: 715–725.CrossRef Parida, V., T. Burström, I. Visnjic, and J. Wincent. 2019. Orchestrating industrial ecosystem in circular economy: A two-stage transformation model for large manufacturing companies. Journal of Business Research 101: 715–725.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Patala, S., L. Albareda, and M. Halme. 2022. Polycentric governance of privately owned resources in circular economy systems. Journal of Management Studies 59 (6): 1563–1596.CrossRef Patala, S., L. Albareda, and M. Halme. 2022. Polycentric governance of privately owned resources in circular economy systems. Journal of Management Studies 59 (6): 1563–1596.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pedneault, J., G. Majeau-Bettez, and M. Margni. 2023. How much sorting is required for a circular low carbon aluminum economy? Journal of Industrial Ecology. 27 (3): 977–992.CrossRef Pedneault, J., G. Majeau-Bettez, and M. Margni. 2023. How much sorting is required for a circular low carbon aluminum economy? Journal of Industrial Ecology. 27 (3): 977–992.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pek, S. 2023. Business and the climate crisis: Toward engagement with climate assemblies. Business & Society 62 (4): 699–703.CrossRef Pek, S. 2023. Business and the climate crisis: Toward engagement with climate assemblies. Business & Society 62 (4): 699–703.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Penrose, E.T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: John Wiley. Penrose, E.T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: John Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Perey, R., S. Benn, R. Agarwal, and M. Edwards. 2018. The place of waste: Changing business value for the circular economy. Business Strategy and the Environment 27: 631–642.CrossRef Perey, R., S. Benn, R. Agarwal, and M. Edwards. 2018. The place of waste: Changing business value for the circular economy. Business Strategy and the Environment 27: 631–642.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Piila, N., M. Sarja, T. Onkila, and M. Mäkelä. 2022. Organisational drivers and challenges in circular economy implementation: An issue life cycle approach. Organization and Environment 35 (4): 523–550.CrossRef Piila, N., M. Sarja, T. Onkila, and M. Mäkelä. 2022. Organisational drivers and challenges in circular economy implementation: An issue life cycle approach. Organization and Environment 35 (4): 523–550.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Plato. 375 BC. The republic. In Ferrari, G.R.F. (ed.), Griffith, Tom (trans.) (2000). Plato. The republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Plato. 375 BC. The republic. In Ferrari, G.R.F. (ed.), Griffith, Tom (trans.) (2000). Plato. The republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Plewnia, F., and E. Guenther. 2021. The transition value of business models for a sustainable energy system: The case of virtual peer-to-peer energy communities. Organization & Environment 34 (3): 479–503.CrossRef Plewnia, F., and E. Guenther. 2021. The transition value of business models for a sustainable energy system: The case of virtual peer-to-peer energy communities. Organization & Environment 34 (3): 479–503.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Plotnitsky, A. 2017. Philosophical Skepticism and Narrative Incredulity. In The Cambridge companion to postmodern American fiction, ed. P. Ghey, 63–80. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Plotnitsky, A. 2017. Philosophical Skepticism and Narrative Incredulity. In The Cambridge companion to postmodern American fiction, ed. P. Ghey, 63–80. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Polanyi, K. 1977. The economistic fallacy. Review 1 (1): 9–18. Polanyi, K. 1977. The economistic fallacy. Review 1 (1): 9–18.
Zurück zum Zitat Polanyi, K. 1944, 2001. The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press. Polanyi, K. 1944, 2001. The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Porter, M.E. 1985a. Competitive advantage; Creating and sustaining superior performance. New York: The Free Press. Porter, M.E. 1985a. Competitive advantage; Creating and sustaining superior performance. New York: The Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Porter, M.E. 1985b. Technology and competitive advantage. Journal of Business Strategy 5 (3): 60–78.CrossRef Porter, M.E. 1985b. Technology and competitive advantage. Journal of Business Strategy 5 (3): 60–78.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Porter, M.E. 1996. What is strategy? Harvard Business Review 74 (December): 61–78. Porter, M.E. 1996. What is strategy? Harvard Business Review 74 (December): 61–78.
Zurück zum Zitat Post, James E., Lee E. Preston, and Sybille Sachs. 2002. Managing the extended enterprise: The new stakeholder view. California Management Review 45 (1): 6–28. Post, James E., Lee E. Preston, and Sybille Sachs. 2002. Managing the extended enterprise: The new stakeholder view. California Management Review 45 (1): 6–28.
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, T.C. 2001. Competitive advantage: Logical and philosophical considerations. Strategic Management Journal 22 (9): 875–888.CrossRef Powell, T.C. 2001. Competitive advantage: Logical and philosophical considerations. Strategic Management Journal 22 (9): 875–888.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pretner, G., N. Darnall, F. Testa, and F. Iraldo. 2021. Are consumers willing to pay for circular products? The role of recycled and second-hand attributes, messaging, and third-party certification. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 175: Article 105888.CrossRef Pretner, G., N. Darnall, F. Testa, and F. Iraldo. 2021. Are consumers willing to pay for circular products? The role of recycled and second-hand attributes, messaging, and third-party certification. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 175: Article 105888.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ranta, V., L. Aarikka-Stenroos, P. Ritala, and S.J. Mäkinen. 2018. Exploring institutional drivers and barriers of the circular economy: A cross-regional comparison of China, the US, and Europe. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 135: 70–82.CrossRef Ranta, V., L. Aarikka-Stenroos, P. Ritala, and S.J. Mäkinen. 2018. Exploring institutional drivers and barriers of the circular economy: A cross-regional comparison of China, the US, and Europe. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 135: 70–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Raworth, K. 2017. Doughnut economics, seven ways to think like a 21st-century economist. London: Random House Business Books. Raworth, K. 2017. Doughnut economics, seven ways to think like a 21st-century economist. London: Random House Business Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Reiter, R., and T. Klenk. 2019. The manifold meanings of ‘post-new public management’–a systematic literature review. International Review of Administrative Sciences 85 (1): 11–27.CrossRef Reiter, R., and T. Klenk. 2019. The manifold meanings of ‘post-new public management’–a systematic literature review. International Review of Administrative Sciences 85 (1): 11–27.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roquebert, C.-I., & G. Debucquet. 2022. Imagining beyond nature-culture dualism: An exploration of ecological justice. Organization 31 (2): 221–246. Roquebert, C.-I., & G. Debucquet. 2022. Imagining beyond nature-culture dualism: An exploration of ecological justice. Organization 31 (2): 221–246.
Zurück zum Zitat Rothbard, M. 2006. Economic thought before Adam Smith. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Rothbard, M. 2006. Economic thought before Adam Smith. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Russo, A., and F. Perrini. 2010. Investigating stakeholder theory and social capital: CSR in large firms and SMEs. Journal of Business ethics 91: 207–221. Russo, A., and F. Perrini. 2010. Investigating stakeholder theory and social capital: CSR in large firms and SMEs. Journal of Business ethics 91: 207–221.
Zurück zum Zitat Sadler-Smith, E., and V. Akstinaite. 2022. Human hubris, anthropogenic climate change, and an environmental ethic of humility. Organization & Environment 35 (3): 446–467.CrossRef Sadler-Smith, E., and V. Akstinaite. 2022. Human hubris, anthropogenic climate change, and an environmental ethic of humility. Organization & Environment 35 (3): 446–467.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Salmivaara, V., and E. Kibler. 2020. “Rhetoric mix” of argumentations: How policy rhetoric conveys meaning of entrepreneurship for sustainable development. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 44 (4): 700–732.CrossRef Salmivaara, V., and E. Kibler. 2020. “Rhetoric mix” of argumentations: How policy rhetoric conveys meaning of entrepreneurship for sustainable development. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 44 (4): 700–732.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schillebeeckx, S.J.D., T. Kautonen, and H. Hakala. 2022. To buy green or not to buy green: Do structural dependencies block ecological responsiveness? Journal of Management 48 (2): 472–501.CrossRef Schillebeeckx, S.J.D., T. Kautonen, and H. Hakala. 2022. To buy green or not to buy green: Do structural dependencies block ecological responsiveness? Journal of Management 48 (2): 472–501.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schultz, F.C., and R.J. Reinhardt. 2022. Facilitating systemic eco-innovation to pave the way for a circular economy: A qualitative-empirical study on barriers and drivers in the European polyurethane industry. Journal of Industrial Ecology 26 (5): 1646–1675.CrossRef Schultz, F.C., and R.J. Reinhardt. 2022. Facilitating systemic eco-innovation to pave the way for a circular economy: A qualitative-empirical study on barriers and drivers in the European polyurethane industry. Journal of Industrial Ecology 26 (5): 1646–1675.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schwarzkopf, S. 2012. The market order as metaphysical loot: Theology and the contested legitimacy of consumer capitalism. Organization 19 (3): 281–297.CrossRef Schwarzkopf, S. 2012. The market order as metaphysical loot: Theology and the contested legitimacy of consumer capitalism. Organization 19 (3): 281–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sherwood, M.W., and J. Pollard. 2018. Responsible investing: An introduction to environmental, social, and governance investments. New York: Routledge.CrossRef Sherwood, M.W., and J. Pollard. 2018. Responsible investing: An introduction to environmental, social, and governance investments. New York: Routledge.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shields, R., and N. Hardy. 2024. Practical aesthesis. Thesis Eleven:07255136241227675. Shields, R., and N. Hardy. 2024. Practical aesthesis. Thesis Eleven:07255136241227675.
Zurück zum Zitat Shipilov, A., and A. Gawer. 2020. Integrating research on interorganizational networks and ecosystems. Academy of Management Annals 14 (1): 92–121. Shipilov, A., and A. Gawer. 2020. Integrating research on interorganizational networks and ecosystems. Academy of Management Annals 14 (1): 92–121.
Zurück zum Zitat Sismondi, J. 1819. Nouveaux príncipes D’economie politique, Ou De la richesse dans ses Rapports avec la population. Paris: Delaunay. Sismondi, J. 1819. Nouveaux príncipes D’economie politique, Ou De la richesse dans ses Rapports avec la population. Paris: Delaunay.
Zurück zum Zitat Sowell, T. 1972. Sismondi: A neglected pioneer. History of Political Economy 4 (1): 62–88.CrossRef Sowell, T. 1972. Sismondi: A neglected pioneer. History of Political Economy 4 (1): 62–88.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Starkey, K., and N. Tiratsoo. 2007. The business school and the bottom line. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Starkey, K., and N. Tiratsoo. 2007. The business school and the bottom line. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stewart, R.E. 1984. Sismondi’s forgotten ethical critique of early capitalism. Journal of Business Ethics 3 (3): 227–234.CrossRef Stewart, R.E. 1984. Sismondi’s forgotten ethical critique of early capitalism. Journal of Business Ethics 3 (3): 227–234.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stough, T., K. Ceulemans, M. Craps, L. van Liedekerke, and V. Cappuyns. 2022. To shift a paradigm or not: Worldviews at play in responsible management education literature. Journal of Management Development 41 (3): 133–146.CrossRef Stough, T., K. Ceulemans, M. Craps, L. van Liedekerke, and V. Cappuyns. 2022. To shift a paradigm or not: Worldviews at play in responsible management education literature. Journal of Management Development 41 (3): 133–146.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sunny, S.A. 2021. “Nature cannot be fooled”: A dual-equilibrium simulation of climate change. Organization and Environment 34 (4): 619–633.CrossRef Sunny, S.A. 2021. “Nature cannot be fooled”: A dual-equilibrium simulation of climate change. Organization and Environment 34 (4): 619–633.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tanguy, A., L. Carrière, and V. Laforest. 2023. Low-tech approaches for sustainability: Key principles from the literature and practice. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 19 (1): 2170143. Tanguy, A., L. Carrière, and V. Laforest. 2023. Low-tech approaches for sustainability: Key principles from the literature and practice. Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy 19 (1): 2170143.
Zurück zum Zitat Temesgen, A., V. Storsletten, and O. Jakobsen. 2021. Circular economy–reducing symptoms or radical change? Philosophy of Management 20 (1): 37–56.CrossRef Temesgen, A., V. Storsletten, and O. Jakobsen. 2021. Circular economy–reducing symptoms or radical change? Philosophy of Management 20 (1): 37–56.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas, L.D., and P. Ritala. 2022. Ecosystem legitimacy emergence: A collective action view. Journal of Management 48 (3): 515–541. Thomas, L.D., and P. Ritala. 2022. Ecosystem legitimacy emergence: A collective action view. Journal of Management 48 (3): 515–541.
Zurück zum Zitat van Bommel, K., A. Rasche, and A. Spicer. 2023. From values to value: The commensuration of sustainability reporting and the crowding out of morality. Organization & Environment 36 (1): 179–206.CrossRef van Bommel, K., A. Rasche, and A. Spicer. 2023. From values to value: The commensuration of sustainability reporting and the crowding out of morality. Organization & Environment 36 (1): 179–206.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van den Bergh, J.C. 2010. Externality or sustainability economics? Ecological Economics 69 (11): 2047–2052.CrossRef Van den Bergh, J.C. 2010. Externality or sustainability economics? Ecological Economics 69 (11): 2047–2052.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Loon, P., C. Delagarde, and L.N. Van Wassenhove. 2018. The role of second-hand markets in circular business: A simple model for leasing versus selling consumer products. International Journal of Production Research 56: 960–973.CrossRef Van Loon, P., C. Delagarde, and L.N. Van Wassenhove. 2018. The role of second-hand markets in circular business: A simple model for leasing versus selling consumer products. International Journal of Production Research 56: 960–973.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Waddock, S. 2022. Transforming economics values toward life: From heterodoxy to orthodoxy. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 31 (1): 274–280.CrossRef Waddock, S. 2022. Transforming economics values toward life: From heterodoxy to orthodoxy. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 31 (1): 274–280.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ward, S. 1997. The social production of postmodern skepticism. Sociological Focus 30 (3): 247–262.CrossRef Ward, S. 1997. The social production of postmodern skepticism. Sociological Focus 30 (3): 247–262.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal 5 (2): 171–180.CrossRef Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal 5 (2): 171–180.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Willman, P., and A. Pepper. 2020. The role played by large firms in generating income inequality: UK FTSE 100 pay practices in the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries. Economy and Society 49 (4): 516–539.CrossRef Willman, P., and A. Pepper. 2020. The role played by large firms in generating income inequality: UK FTSE 100 pay practices in the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries. Economy and Society 49 (4): 516–539.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wu, D., and X. Li. forthcoming. The curvilinear relationship between corporate social responsibility and competitive advantage: Empirical evidence from China. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 33 (1): 40–64. Wu, D., and X. Li. forthcoming. The curvilinear relationship between corporate social responsibility and competitive advantage: Empirical evidence from China. Business Ethics, the Environment & Responsibility 33 (1): 40–64.
Zurück zum Zitat Xu, M., G.T. Daigger, C. Xi, J. Liu, J. Qu, P.J. Alvarez, P. Biswas, Y. Chen, D. Dolinoy, Y. Fan, and H.O. Gao. 2021. US–China collaboration is vital to global plans for a healthy environment and sustainable development. Environmental Science & Technology 55 (14): 9622–9626.CrossRef Xu, M., G.T. Daigger, C. Xi, J. Liu, J. Qu, P.J. Alvarez, P. Biswas, Y. Chen, D. Dolinoy, Y. Fan, and H.O. Gao. 2021. US–China collaboration is vital to global plans for a healthy environment and sustainable development. Environmental Science & Technology 55 (14): 9622–9626.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yonatany, M. 2017. Platforms, ecosystems, and the internationalization of highly digitized organizations. Journal of Organization Design 6: 1–5. Yonatany, M. 2017. Platforms, ecosystems, and the internationalization of highly digitized organizations. Journal of Organization Design 6: 1–5.
Zurück zum Zitat Zagorin, P. 1999. History, the referent, and narrative: Reflections on postmodernism now. History and Theory 38 (1): 1–24.CrossRef Zagorin, P. 1999. History, the referent, and narrative: Reflections on postmodernism now. History and Theory 38 (1): 1–24.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Metaphysical Status of Money and Sustainable Organizations and Ecosystems
verfasst von
Tiago Cardao-Pito
Jyldyz Abdyrakhmanova
Publikationsdatum
25.04.2024
Verlag
Springer International Publishing
Erschienen in
Philosophy of Management
Print ISSN: 1740-3812
Elektronische ISSN: 2052-9597
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s40926-024-00309-z

Premium Partner